A thought provoking discussion....
Arizona Legal Studies
Discussion Paper No. 0935
Underwater and Not Walking Away:
Shame, Fear and the Social Management of the
Housing Crisis
Brent T. White
The University of Arizona
James E. Rogers College of Law
November 2009
Underwater and Not Walking Away:
Shame, Fear and the Social Management of the Housing Crisis
Brent T. White*
Abstract
Despite reports that homeowners are increasingly
“walking away” from their mortgages, most homeowners continue
to make their payments even when they are significantly
underwater. This article suggests that most homeowners choose
not to strategically default as a result of two emotional forces: 1)
the desire to avoid the shame and guilt of foreclosure; and 2)
exaggerated anxiety over foreclosure’s perceived consequences.
Moreover, these emotional constraints are actively cultivated by
the government and other social control agents in order to
encourage homeowners to follow social and moral norms related
to the honoring of financial obligations - and to ignore market and
legal norms under which strategic default might be both viable and
the wisest financial decision. Norms governing homeowner
behavior stand in sharp contrast to norms governing lenders, who
seek to maximize profits or minimize losses irrespective of
concerns of morality or social responsibility. This norm
asymmetry leads to distributional inequalities in which individual
homeowners shoulder a disproportionate burden from the housing
collapse.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
I. Introduction ......................................................................... 1
II. Underwater and Staying Put ............................................... 3
III. The Financial Logic of Walking Away .............................. 7
IV. Explaining Homeowner Choices ...................................... 13
V. The Social Control of the Housing Crisis ......................... 23
VI. The Asymmetry of Homeowner and Lender Norms ........ 35
VII. Leveling the Playing Field ................................................ 40
*
Associate Professor Law, University of Arizona, James E. Rogers
College of Law.
I. Introduction
Millions of homeowners in the United States are
“underwater” on their mortgages, meaning that they owe more than
their homes are worth.1 Yet, despite all the concern over
homeowners who are simply “walking away” from their homes,2
While such behavior may appear irrational on its face,
the vast majority of underwater homeowners continue to make
their mortgage payments - even when they are hundreds of
thousands of dollars underwater and have no reasonable prospect
of recouping their losses. This includes underwater homeowners
that live in “non-recourse states” such as California and Arizona,
where lenders cannot pursue defaulting homeowners for a
deficiency judgment.
3
behavioral economists explain that underwater homeowners simply
suffer from the same kind of cognitive biases that lead individuals
to make other suboptimal economic decisions.4
The behavioral economic explanation doesn’t account,
however, for homeowners who are fully aware that it would be in
Underwater
homeowners aren’t knowingly making bad choices, they just can’t
cognitively grasp that they would be better off if they walked away
from their mortgages.
1
See, e.g., First American CoreLogic, Negative Equity Report (Aug.
13, 2009)(reporting that 15.2 million U.S. mortgages were underwater in the
second quarter of 2009); See also October Oversight Report: An Assessment of
Foreclosure Mitigation Efforts after Six Months, Congressional Oversight Panel
25 (October 9, 2009)(reporting that between 15-17 million homeowners are, or
soon may be, underwater).
2
See, e.g., David Streitfeld, When Debtors Decide to Default, N.Y.
TIMES, July 25, 2009; Brian Eckhouse, More Homeowners Wrestling With
Ethics of Walking Away, LAS VEGAS SUN, March 23, 2009; John A. Schoen,
Why It’s a Bad Idea to Walk Away From the Mortgage, MSNBC, March 16,
2009; Fox Business: Some Homeowners Who Can’t Pay Choosing to Just Walk
Away (Fox television broadcast company Feb. 19, 2009); Liz Pulliam Weston,
When to Walk Away From a Mortgage, MSN MONEY, June 5, 2008;K Barbara
Kiviat, Walking Away From Your Mortgage, TIME June 19, 2008; 60 Minutes:
The U.S. Mortgage Meltdown (CBS broadcast May 25, 2008) available at
http://www.cbsnews.com/video/watch/?id=4126094n&tag=related;photovideo;
Economy: Why Not Just Walk Away From A Home? (NPR radio broadcast Feb.
13, 2008) available at
http://www.npr.org/templates/story/story.php?storyId=18958049
3
Yongheng Deng & John M. Quigley, Woodhead Behavior and the
Pricing of Residential Mortgages 3-4 (Berkeley Program on Hous. and Urban
Pol., Working Paper No. W00-004, 2004), available at
http://urbanpolicy.berkeley.edu/pdf/DQ_Woodhead_Web.pdf.
4
See Peter Ubel, Human Nature and the Financial Crisis, FORBES,
Feb. 22, 2009, http://www.forbes.com/2009/02/20/behavioral-economics-
mortgage-opinions-contributors_financial_crisis.html.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
2
their financial best interest to default, but still don’t do so. This
article suggest that most underwater homeowners don’t default as a
result of two emotional forces: 1) the desire to avoid the shame or
guilt associated with foreclosure; and 2) fear over the perceived
consequences of foreclosure - consequences that are in actuality
much less severe than most homeowners have been led to believe.
Moreover, fear, shame, and guilt are not mere “transaction
costs” that homeowners calculate according to their own personal
tolerance for each. Rather, these emotional constraints are actively
cultivated by the government, the financial industry, and other
social control agents in order to induce individual homeowners to
act in ways that are against their own self interest, but which are -
wrongly this article contends - argued to be socially beneficial.
Unlike lenders who seek to maximize profits irrespective of
concerns of morality or social responsibility, individual
homeowners are encouraged to behave in accordance with social
and moral norms requiring that individuals keep promises and
honor financial obligations. Thus, individual homeowners tend to
ignore market and legal norms under which strategic default might
not only be a viable option but also the wisest financial decision.
Lenders, on the other hand, have generally resisted calls to modify
underwater mortgages despite the fact that it would be both
socially beneficial and morally responsible for them to do so. This
norm asymmetry has lead to distributional inequalities in which
individual homeowners shoulder a disproportionate burden from
the housing collapse.
This article proceeds as follows: Section II shows that,
despite widespread concern that underwater homeowners are
simply walking away, the vast majority of underwater homeowners
have not strategically defaulted on their mortgages. Section III
explores the financial logic of walking away from an underwater
mortgage and suggests that many more homeowners should be
strategically defaulting. Section IV argues that though cognitive
biases may account for many underwater homeowners’ decisions
not to strategically default, emotions such as shame, guilt, and fear
play the largest role in homeowner decisions to knowingly eschew
“in the money” default options. Section V argues that social
control agents such as the government, the media, and the financial
industry use both moral suasion and disinformation to cultivate
these emotional constraints in homeowners. It also argues that
credit rating agencies play a central role as enforcers of moral and
social norms against walking away from one’s mortgage. Section
VI argues that the disparity between the norms governing the
behavior of individuals and banks has created an imbalance in
which individual homeowners have born a disproportionate
financial burden from the housing collapse. Section VII explores
Underwater and Not Walking Away
3
ways to either address the distributional inequalities of norm
asymmetry or to empower homeowners to renegotiate underwater
mortgages on a more level playing field with lenders.
II. Underwater and Staying Put
As of June 2009, more than 32% of all mortgaged
properties in the U.S. were “underwater,” meaning that the
homeowner owed more on their mortgage than their home was
worth.5 This percentage is expected to increase to 48% by the first
quarter of 2011,6 by which time housing prices in the largest 100
metropolitan areas are predicted to have dropped 42% from their
peak.7 The national numbers hide the full extent of the problem,
however, as the percentage of underwater mortgages is much
higher in the regions suffering the worst price declines. For
example, as of June 30, 2009, 66 percent of mortgage borrowers
were already underwater in Nevada, 51 percent were underwater in
Arizona, 49 percent were underwater in Florida, 48 percent were
underwater in Michigan, and 42 percent were underwater in
California.8 As shown in the chart below, the percentage of
underwater mortgages is higher still if one isolates the hardest hit
metropolitan areas:9
Metropolitan
Statistical Area Current Percent
Underwater
Merced, CA 85
El Centro, CA 85
Modesto, CA 84
Las Vegas, NV 81
Stockton, CA 81
Bakersfield, CA 79
Port St. Lucie, FL 79
Riverside-San Bernardino, CA 78
5
First American CoreLogic, Negative Equity Report (Aug. 13, 2009).
“The aggregate property value for loans in a negative equity position was $3.4
trillion…. In California, the aggregate value of homes that are in negative equity
was $969 billion, followed by Florida ($432 billion), New Jersey ($146 billion),
Illinois ($146 billion) and Arizona ($140 billion). Los Angeles had over $310
billion in aggregate property value in a negative equity position, followed by
New York ($183 billion), Miami ($152 billion), Washington, DC ($149 billion)
and Chicago ($134 billion).” Id.
6
Drowning in Debt – A Look at “Underwater” Homeowners 4,
Deutsche Bank, August 5, 2009. (on file with author)(also noting that “41% of
prime conforming borrowers and 46% of prime jumbo borrowers will be
underwater”)
7
Update: The Outlook For U.S. Home Prices, Deutsche Bank, June 15,
2009 (on file with author)
8
First American CoreLogic, Negative Equity Report (Aug. 13, 2009).
9
Percentages from Drowning in Debt, supra note 6.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
4
Cape Coral-Fort Myers, FL 76
Yuba City, CA 73
Madera, CA 72
Fresno, CA 72
Orlando-Kissimmee, FL 71
Visalia-Porterville, CA 70
Miami-Miami Beach, FL 70
Palm Bay-Titusville, FL 69
Lakeland-Winter Haven, FL 69
Phoenix-Mesa-Scottsdale, AZ 68
As of the second quarter of 2009, over 16% of homeowners
had negative equity exceeding 20% of their home’s value, and over
22% of homeowners had negative equity exceeding 10% of their
home’s value.10 Again, however, the situation is worse in the
hardest hit markets. For example, 47% percent of homeowners in
Nevada had negative equity exceeding 25% of their home’s value,
as did 30% of homeowners in Florida, 29% in Arizona, and 25% in
California. Moreover, given the high median home prices at the
peak within these markets, a large percentage of these homeowners
are underwater by hundreds of thousands of dollars.11
The extent of the negative equity problem is a significant
contributing factor to a combined foreclosure and 30+ day
delinquency rate for home mortgages exceeding 13 percent, a
historic high.
12
10
First American CoreLogic, Negative Equity Report (Aug. 13, 2009).
However, the high foreclosure and delinquency
11
Id. For example, a homeowner who bought a home in 2006 in
Salinas, California, where home prices have dropped 70% from the peak, has on
average $214,000 in negative equity. Luigi Guiso, Paola Sapienza & Luigi
Zingales, Moral and Social Constraints to Strategic Default on Mortgages 2
(Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 15145, July 2009)
Moreover, given that average home prices reached over $580,000 in Salinas at
the peak, homeowners who bought even slightly better-than-average homes
could easily have negative equity exceeding $300,000. The story is the same,
of course, in other California metro areas, including Los Angeles, Modesto, El
Centro, Merced, Riverside, and Redding. The situation is also dire outside of
California. A homeowner who bought an average home near the peak in Las
Vegas for example – where prices have dropped 52% - would likely have
negative equity in excess of $120,000. The situation is the same in Miami
where prices are down 48%, and in Phoenix, where prices have dropped 54%.
Furthermore, with such significant price decreases in each of these markets, a
large number of individuals who bought more-expensive-than-average homes
have negative equity easily topping $200,000 to $300,000. Standard &
Poor’s/Case-Schiller, Home Price Values for July 2009 (Sep. 29, 2009)(on file
with author)
12
As of the second quarter of 2009, the foreclosure rate was 4.3 percent
and the delinquency rate (meaning here loans that were 30+ days delinquent)
was 8.86 percent, for a combined rate of 13.13. “The delinquency rate includes
loans that are at least one payment past due but does not include loans
somewhere in the process of foreclosure.” Mortgage Bankers Association,
National Delinquency Survey 2009 2nd Quarter (Aug. 20, 2009). See also
Underwater and Not Walking Away
5
rate is not caused by large percentages of homeowners voluntarily
walking from their homes, even though they can afford the
payments. To the contrary, only about one-fourth of homeowner
defaults are strategic, with the other three-fourths triggered by job
losses, divorce or other financial difficulties, which when
combined with negative equity give homeowners no option but to
let go of their homes.13 In other words, for the vast majority of
homeowners, negative equity is a necessary but not a sufficient
condition for default. Moreover, the vast majority of defaults have
involved subprime14 or Alt-A loans15 – with over 47 percent of
subprime loans non-performing as of the second quarter of 2009.16
In contrast, the combined default rate for prime loans was only
5.44 percent.17 Put in perspective, these statistics mean that
though more than 32% of U.S. homeowners were underwater on
their mortgages by the end of the second quarter of 2009, the
strategic default rate was roughly 3%.18
Christopher L Foote,., Kristopher S. Gerardi, Lorenz Goette, and Paul S. Willen,
Reducing Foreclosures 5, Public Policy Discussion Papers, April 8, 2009
(noting that the empirical evidence on the role of negative equity in contributing
to foreclosures is “incontrovertible.”) Available at http://www.bos.frb.
Org/economic/ppdp/2009/ppdp0902.htm
13
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 1; see News Release, Federal Housing
Finance Agency, FHFA Reports Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Foreclosure
Prevention Efforts for May (Aug. 3, 2009),
http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/14723/MayForeclosure_Prevention8309.pdf
(noting that the top five reasons for delinquency are income loss (34%),
excessive obligations (20%), unemployment (8%), illness of principal mortgagor
(6%), and marital difficulties (6%).”)
14
A mortgage loan is subprime if the borrower has an imperfect credit
history and/or high debt-to-income ratio. “Subprime borrowers generally have a
credit (FICO) score between 580 and 660.” Drowning in Debt – A Look at
“Underwater” Homeowners 3, Deutsche Bank, August 5, 2009
15
Mortgage Bankers Association, National Delinquency Survey 2009
2nd Quarter (Aug. 20, 2009) “Alt-A loans were typically originated with
reduced documentation to home borrowers with limited credit history… Alt-A
borrowers have higher FICO scores (660-720) than subprime borrowers. Also,
relatively high concentrations of investor properties are common in
securitizations of Alt-A mortgage loans.” Drowning in Debt – A Look at
“Underwater” Homeowners 3, Deutsche Bank, August 5, 2009.
16
Laurie Goodman, et. al., Housing Overhang/Shadow Inventory =
Enormous Problem 8, Memorandum, Amherst Mortgage Insight, September 23,
2009 (on file with author)
17
Mortgage Bankers Association, National Delinquency Survey 2009
2nd Quarter (Aug. 20, 2009) However, as the subprime crisis has mostly run its
course, prime fixed-rate loans now account for one in three foreclosure starts.
Id.
18
Mortgage Bankers Association, National Delinquency Survey 2009;
and 1.9 Million Foreclosure Filings Reported on More than 1.5 Million U.S.
Properties in First Half of 2009, RealtyTrac, (July 15, 2009),
http://www.realtytrac.com/ContentManagement/PressRelease.aspx?channelid=9
&ItemID=6802 [hereinafter Foreclosure Filings Reported] . For a historical
Underwater and Not Walking Away
6
As further evidence that relatively few homeowners
strategically default solely because they are underwater, housing
markets with a sharply higher percentage of underwater
homeowners as compared to the national average do not have
sharply higher default rates. For example, although almost 51% of
Arizona homeowners were underwater (compared to 32%
nationally) in the second quarter of 2009, the combined foreclosure
and 30+ day deficiency rate in Arizona was 16.3% – only slightly
above the national average of 13%.19
As the chart below
illustrates, this pattern of relatively low default rates compared to
the percentage of underwater mortgages holds true almost
universally across the hardest hit markets, with the default rate
much more closely resembling the unemployment rate than the
percent underwater:
Metropolitan
Statistical Area Percent
underwater20 Serious
Delinquency
Rate
21
Unemployment
Rate
22
Merced, CA
85 18.99 17.5
Modesto, CA 84 15.10 16.1
Las Vegas-Paradise,
NV 81 15.53 11.3
Stockton, CA 81 16.20 15.5
Bakersfield, CA 79 11.92 13.9
Port St. Lucie, FL 79 17.30 14.1
Riverside-San
Bernardino-Ontario,
CA
78 15.19 13.7
Orlando-Kissimmee,
FL 71 16.63 10.7
Palm Bay-Melbourne-
Titusville, FL 69 10.92 11.1
Lakeland-Winter
Haven, FL 69 14.05 11.9
Phoenix-Mesa-
Scottsdale, AZ 68 10.09 7.7
Tampa-St. Petersburg- 65 11.71 11.2
comparison see Drowning in Debt – A Look at “Underwater” Homeowners
supra note ___ at 14 (noting that 7% of homeowners with negative equity
defaulted during the housing bust in Boston in the 1980’s and 90’s)
19
Mortgage Bankers Association, National Delinquency Survey 2009
2nd Quarter (Aug. 20, 2009)
20
Drowning in Debt – A Look at “Underwater” Homeowners 10,
Deutsche Bank, August 5, 2009
21
The seriously delinquent rate is the combined percentage of
mortgages more than 90 days delinquent or in foreclosure. Risk View: Spatial
Patterns of Mortgage Deliquency in Major U.S. Metropolitan Areas, First
American CoreLogic Newsletter, June 2009 (on file with author)
22
Update: The Outlook For U.S. Home Prices 24-25, Deutsche Bank,
June 15, 2009
Underwater and Not Walking Away
7
Clearwater, FL
West Palm Beach –
Boca Raton, FL 64 15.28 11.2
Salinas, CA 51 12.62 11.7
These numbers strongly suggest that factors other than
strategic defaults are driving the delinquency rate, with
unemployment the most likely culprit.23 Indeed, given the striking
disparity between the percentage of underwater homeowners and
the percentage of defaults, the real mystery is not - as media
coverage has suggested - why large numbers of homeowners are
walking away, but why, given the percentage of underwater
mortgages, more homeowners are not. 24
III. The Financial Logic of Walking Away
Before examining why more underwater homeowners are
not strategically defaulting, it might be helpful to explore why they
should. A textbook premise of economics is that the value of a
home, even an owner occupied one, is “the current value of the
rent payments that could be earned from renting the property at
23
See October Oversight Report: An Assessment of Foreclosure
Mitigation Efforts after Six Months, Congressional Oversight Panel 20-21
(discussing “fifth wave” of foreclosures caused by unemployment); Update: The
Outlook For U.S. Home Prices 9, Deutsche Bank, March 15, 2009 (on file with
author)(discussing the role of unemployment as the primary risk factor for
default).; and Alan Zibel, Foreclosures rise 5 percent from summer to fall,
ASSOCIATED PRESS WIRE, October 15, 2009 (on file with author)(reporting that
“Unemployment is the main reason homeowners are falling into trouble. While
the economy is likely out of recession, the unemployment rate — now at a 26-
year high of 9.8 percent — isn't expected to peak until the middle of next year.”)
Information for the Miami-Fort Lauderdale area is excluded from this chart due
to the high concentration of non-owner occupied investment properties in the
Miami-Fort Lauderdale area area, resulting in a deficiency rate more than double
the unemployment rate. See Kate Barry, Wary of Default, Banks Curtail Loans
to Investors, American Banker, October 13, 1009 (nothing that, many real estate
investors “in second-home markets” such as Miami . Las Vegas, and Phoenix
“simply turned in their keys to banks, defaulting on scores of second homes and
investment properties that they had intended to flip.”) See also Drowning in
Debt – A Look at “Underwater” Homeowners 10, Deutsche Bank, August 5,
2009 (listing underwater percentage for the Miami MSA of 70 percent and 69
percent for the Fort Lauderdale MSA); Risk View: Spatial Patterns of Mortgage
Deliquency in Major U.S. Metropolitan Areas, First American CoreLogic
Newsletter, June 2009 (on file with author) (listing serious delinquency rate for
the Miami MSA of 22.14 percent and 18.12 percent for the Fort Lauderdale
MSA); and Update: The Outlook For U.S. Home Prices 25, Deutsche Bank,
June 15, 2009 (listing unemployment rate in Miami of 8.5 percent and 9.3
percent in the Fort Lauderdale MSA).
24
For examples of the media hype regarding the purported walk away
phenomenon see, supra note 1.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
8
market prices.”25
In calculating whether to buy or rent, a potential
homebuyer should compare the net cost of owning to the net cost
of renting a similar home over the expected period of occupancy.
The costs of owning include the interest-only portion of the loan
payment, property taxes, maintenance, homeowners insurance, and
transaction costs upon selling, minus the expected appreciation and
cumulative tax savings over the planned period of ownership. As
a rule of thumb, a potential homebuyer is generally better off
renting when the home price exceeds 15 or 16 times the annual
rent for comparable homes.
In other words, when the net cost of buying a
home exceeds the net cost of renting, one is better off renting.
The equation is not as simple, however, as comparing total
mortgage payments to rent payments because home ownership
carries certain benefits including tax breaks and the potential for
appreciation. Additionally, assuming a non-depreciating market,
the portion of the mortgage payment that goes to principal rather
than interest will eventually inure to the homeowner at the time of
sale. On the flip side, homeownership carries significant costs
that renting does not, including maintenance, homeowner’s
insurance and substantial transaction costs upon selling.
26
The calculation for a rational homeowner in deciding
whether to strategically default on a home mortgage is similar to
that for buying in that base calculation is still the cost of renting
verses the cost of continuing to own.
27
However, the underwater
homeowner has additional considerations, including existing
negative equity on the one hand and the costs of foreclosure on the
other.28
25
HYE JIN RHO, ET. AL., CHANGING PROSPECTS FOR BUILDING HOME
EQUITY 3, (2008), available at
http://www.cepr.net/documents/publications/Changing_Prospects_for_Building
_Home_Equity_2008_10.pdf
Even leaving aside these foreclosure costs, the calculation
as to whether one is financially better off defaulting requires one to
consider several additional variables for which one may not have
good information. These variables include a reasonable estimate
of the current value of one’s home, the cost to rent a similar home,
an idea of how long one intends to stay in the home, and an
26
Id. at 4. Historical home prices have hewed to a price-to-annual-rent
ratio of roughly 15 to 1 - except during bubbles. Id.
27
As a caveat, for homeowners with sufficient resources to purchase
another home before bailing on the first, the calculation might actually be the
cost of buying a new home (rather than renting) verse continuing to own their
current home. See Nick Timiraos, Some Buy a New Home and Bail on the Old,
Wall St. J., June 11, 2008.
28
See, Joshua Rosner, Housing in the New Millennium: A Home
Without Equity is Just a Rental with Debt (June 29, 2001); available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1162456 (discussing how lack of equity changes the
default calculation)
Underwater and Not Walking Away
9
estimate of the average appreciation or depreciation one’s home is
likely to experience over that period of time. While each variable
requires some guessing, there is a wealth of information available
to assist homeowners in making rational estimates – should they
endeavor to do so.29
With these estimates in hand, a homeowner also needs to
know the current principal balance on their mortgage(s), the
monthly interest-only portion of the mortgage(s), monthly
mortgage insurance, if any, the amount monthly taxes, insurance,
and homeowners association dues, if any, and their annual tax
savings from owning verses renting. A rational homeowner can
then make relatively simple calculations as to how much money
they would save or lose by walking away, both on a monthly basis
and over time. They can also predict out how long it will take to
recover their equity.
30
Consider, for example, Sam and Chris, a young
professional couple with two small children, who stretched to buy
their first home - an average 3 bedroom, 1380 square foot house in
Salinas, California – for $585,000 in January of 2006.
31
29
For example, both Zillow.com and the Home Price Calculator at
Sam and
Chris had excellent credit and a solid income, and were thus able
to qualify for a 30-year fixed interest loan with nothing down. At
http://www.fhfa.gov/ can provide most homeowners with a reasonably accurate
estimate of their home’s value. Or, if a home is particularly unique, one can
have their home appraised by professional appraiser. Similarly, one could have
a real estate management company give an estimate as to how much one’s home
would rent for or simply look in the newspaper and online to see what similar
homes are renting for. Moreover, there are considerable amounts of market-
specific research available on the internet which can help rational individuals
predict the amount of appreciation or depreciation their home is likely to
experience over a given period of time. See, e.g., HYE JIN RHO, ET. AL.,
CHANGING PROSPECTS FOR BUILDING HOME EQUITY (2008), available at
http://www.cepr.net/documents/publications/Changing_Prospects_for_Building
_Home_Equity_2008_10.pdf; Where Home Prices Are Hitting Bottom,
FORBES.COM, (September 18, 2009) http://www.forbes.com/2009/09/18/home-
prices-bottoming-lifestyle-real-estate-home-prices.html; and Why Housing
Hasn't Bottomed, FORBES.COM, (October 15, 2009)
http://www.forbes.com/2009/10/15/real-estate-ownership-markets-equities-
renting.html. Or a rational individual in a non-depreciating market might simply
count on appreciation around the historical home appreciation rate of 3-4% per
year. HYE JIN RHO, ET. AL, supra note 27.
30
For the mathematically challenged, there are online calculators, such
as one at YouWalkAway.com, that do these calculations automatically. See,
http://www.youwalkaway.com/output24/InterectiveFlashCalculator.html (last
visited Sep. 26, 2009).
31
This example is a hypothetical based upon the peak cost of an
average priced, and average sized, home in Salanis in January 2006. See Zillow,
Salinas Overview, http://www.zillow.com/local-info/CA-Salinas/r_54288/ (last
visited June 30, 2009)(listing 585,000 as the average home price in January
2006).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
10
an interest rate of 6.5%, their total monthly payment is $4300,32
Unfortunately for Sam and Chris, the housing market began
to collapse in 2007. Though they still owe about $560,000 on their
home,
which is just under 31% of their gross monthly income, and within
the payment-to-income ratio considered “affordable” by most
lenders. However, after paying for taxes, health insurance, student
loans, childcare, automobiles, food, and other necessities, Sam and
Chris do well to break even each month. At the time they bought
their home, they were not overly concerned about this - as they
saw their mortgage payment itself as an investment in their own
and their children’s futures.
33
it is now only worth $187,000.34 A similar house around
the corner from Sam and Chris recently listed for $179,000, which,
with a modest 5% down, would translate to a total monthly
payment of less than $1200 per month – as compared to the $4300
that they currently pay. They could rent a similar house in the
neighborhood for about $1000.35
Assuming they intend to stay in their home ten years, Sam
and Chris would save approximately $340,000 by walking away,
including a monthly savings of at least $1700 on rent verses
mortgage payments, even after factoring in the mortgage interest
tax reduction. The financial gain for Sam and Chris from walking
away would be even more substantial if they took their monthly
savings and put it into an investment account. If they stay in their
home on the other hand, it will take Sam and Chris over 60 years
just to recover their equity – assuming, of course, that they live that
long, the market in Salinas has indeed hit bottom, and their home
appreciates at the historical appreciation rate of 3.5%.
36
Millions of homeowners who bought homes in the last five
years are in similar situations to Sam and Chris, particularly in the
hardest hit states of California, Florida, Nevada, and Arizona. For
example, a homeowner who bought an average home in Miami at
32
This calculation assumes a loan of $585,000 at 6.5%, mortgage
insurance of $233, taxes $250, and homeowners insurance of $120. Id.
33
Calculation based upon amortization at 42 months, with
approximately $650 going toward principal each month. The remaining $3700
of the payment is interest, taxes and insurance.
34
This price is based upon Zillow data for Salinas, CA. Zillow, Salinas
Overview, http://www.zillow.com/local-info/CA-Salinas/r_54288/ (last visited
June 30, 2009)(indicating that the average home reached $585,000 in 2006 and
that the average home is now worth $187,000).
35
Based upon prices of homes currently listed for sale on Zillow in
Salinas, CA, id., and average rent identified in HYE JIN RHO, ET. AL., supra note
25
36
HYE JIN RHO ET AL. supra note 25 (indicating that historical
appreciation rates for home prices have been between 3% and 4%.)
Underwater and Not Walking Away
11
the peak would have paid around $355,400.37 That home would
now be worth only $198,00038 and, assuming a 5% down payment,
the homeowner would have approximately $132,000 in negative
equity.39 He could save approximately $116,000 by walking away
and renting a comparable home.40 Or, he could stay and take 20
years just to recover lost equity – all the while throwing away
$1300 a month in net savings that he could invest elsewhere. The
advantage of walking is even starker for the large percentage of
individuals who bought more-expensive-than-average homes in the
Miami area – or in any bubble market for that matter41 - in the last
five years. Millions of U.S. homeowners could save hundreds of
thousands of dollars by strategically defaulting on their
mortgages.42
Homeowners should be walking away in droves. But they
aren’t. And it’s not because the financial costs of foreclosure
outweigh the benefits. To be sure, foreclosure comes with costs,
including a significant negative impact on one’s credit rating.
43
But assuming one had otherwise good credit, and continues to
meet other credit obligations, one can have a good credit rating
again – meaning above 660 - within two years after a foreclosure.44
37
Zillow, Miami Home Prices, Home Values, and Property Values,
http://www.zillow.com/local-info/FL-Miami-home-value/r_12700/ (last visited
Sep. 7, 2009).
38
Id.
39
Id. (assumes 5% down with an interest rate at national average of
6.5% for June 2007).
40
Assumes monthly interest of $1824, mortgage insurance of $219,
taxes of $500, and homeowners insurance of $100, with $329,830 balance
remaining on the mortgage. The estimate for mortgage insurance is from
http://www.goodmortgage.com/Calc_PMI.htm.
41
See HYE JIN RHO, ET. AL., supra note 25, at 17 (listing“bubble
markets”).
42
Average national numbers show that home prices have declined 25%
nationally from $240,000 at the peak to $184,000 in June of 2009. See Zillow,
Real Estate Market Reports, http://www.zillow.com/local-
info/#metric=mt%3D34%26dt%3D1%26tp%3D5%26rt%3D14%26r%3D10200
1 (last visited Oct. 9, 2009).
43
Just how much impact a foreclosure has on one’s credit is unclear
because the Fair-Isaac Company will not share this information. But generally
one can expect a 100 to 150 point hit to his or her credit as a result of a
foreclosure, and additional hits for each late payment – which are generally
reported separately from the foreclosure itself. See How Foreclosures, Short
Sales, and Bankruptcies Affect Your Credit Score, AMERICAN BANKING NEWS,
Oct. 8, 2009, http://www.articlesbase.com/real-estate-articles/how-does-
foreclosure-impact-your-credit-report-234979.html. The total hit from late
payments and a foreclosure could be as much as 300 to 400 points.
Additionally, one must wait seven years before the foreclosure disappears from
one’s credit report entirely. Id.
44
See Marilyn Kennedy Melia, Life After Foreclosure, Bankrate.com,
http://www.bankrate.com/finance/mortgages/life-after-foreclosure-2.aspx (last
visited Oct. 9, 2009) (noting, “If a foreclosure is an isolated event on an
Underwater and Not Walking Away
12
Additionally, in as little as three years, one can qualify for a
federally-insured FHA loan to purchase another home.45
While the actual financial cost of having a poor credit score
for a few years may be hard to quantify, it is not likely to be
significant for most individuals – especially not when compared to
the savings from walking away from a seriously underwater
mortgage. While a good credit score might save an average person
ten of thousands of dollars over the course of a lifetime, a few
years of poor credit shouldn’t cost more than few thousand dollars.
Moreover, one who plans to strategically default can take steps to
minimize even this marginal cost. For example, one could
purchase a new vehicle, secure a new home to rent, or even
purchase a new house before beginning the process of defaulting
on one’s mortgage. Most individuals should be able to plan in
advance for a few years of limited credit.
There are, of course, costs to foreclosure other than
temporarily poor credit. These include moving costs and possible
transportation costs if one is required to live further from work or
school. But again, these costs are minimal when compared to the
savings of shedding a home that is hundreds of thousands of
dollars underwater. The most significant financial risk from a
foreclosure is the risk of a deficiency judgment or, in the
alternative, tax liability for the unsatisfied portion of one’s loan
upon foreclosure. But even these potential costs are significantly
less than one might expect. First, a number of states – including
many with the biggest declines in home values - are non-recourse
states, meaning that lenders may not pursue homeowners for a
deficiency judgment if the home was their primary residence.
Second, even in recourse states, lenders rarely pursue borrowers
for deficiency judgments unless they have special reason to suspect
otherwise good credit record, consumers may be able to rehabilitate their record
and garner better loans and card rates in 24 months”); see also
CreditScoreQuick.com, Revive Credit Report after Foreclosure,
http://www.creditscorequick.com/2008/03/revive-credit-report-after-
foreclosure.html (site last visited Sept. 26, 2009) (“Your credit report might
recover quickly as long as you have other good standing credit reporting on your
credit report.”)
45
CreditScoreQuick.com, Mortgages Fixes and Your Credit Score,
http://www.creditscorequick.com/2009/08/mortgage-fixes-and-your-credit-
scores.html (site last visited September 26, 2009). Because banks are often
much more willing to negotiate a short sale once it becomes clear that a
homeowner intends to default, strategically default need not result, and often
does not result, in a foreclosure. The negative effect of a short sale one’s credit
is significantly less than a foreclosure and depends on the negotiated agreement
between the borrower and the lender. For example, if the lender agrees to report
the loan as “paid,” there is no negative impact, whereas if the lender reports it
“settled,” the negative impact can be quite significant. Id.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
13
the borrower has means to pay it. 46 This is particularly true to the
extent that the home is in a state where lenders are overwhelmed
with foreclosures.47 Third, tax regulations have recently changed
to waive taxes on the unpaid portion of a mortgage upon
foreclosure, which was previously classified as income to the
borrower if the lender reported it as such.48
In short, the financial costs of foreclosure, while not
insignificant, are minimal compared to the financial benefit of
strategic default – particularly for seriously underwater
homeowners.
49
IV. Explaining Homeowner Choices
For many, default is the “in the money” option by
any objective measure. Yet most seriously underwater
homeowners aren’t walking away - even as they sink deeper into
negative equity.
It might be tempting to label such underwater homeowners
“woodheads,” a term sometimes applied in economic literature to
individuals who choose not to act in their own self-interest.50
46
See e.g., Oren Bar-Gill, The Law, Economics and Psychology of
Subprime Mortgage Contracts, 94 CORNELL L. REV. 1073 (2009) (finding that
even in recourse states, deficiency actions are often not cost-effective for the
lender, thus turning recourse loans into de-facto non-recourse loans)
But
labeling such behavior irrational does little to explain its existence.
One possible explanation is that the low rate of strategic default is
not the result of irrational decision-making at all, but rather the
result of utility maximizing calculations by homeowners. In other
words, it could be that underwater homeowners generally
understand that they could save hundreds of thousands of dollars
by defaulting on their mortgages, but they simply value their
homes (in which they may have “made large financial, emotional,
47
See Peter S.Goodman, Paper Avalanche Buries Plan to Stem
Foreclosures, N.Y. TIMES, June 29, 2009,
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/06/29/business/29loanmod.html
48
The Mortgage Debt Relief Act of 2007 excludes income from the
discharge of debt on principal residences. Debt reduced through mortgage
restructuring, as well as mortgage debt forgiven in connection with a
foreclosure, qualifies for the relief. This provision applies to debt forgiven in
calendar years 2007 through 2012.
49
As discussed above, a significant portion of homeowners fall into the
“seriously underwater” category. For example, 47% percent of homeowners in
Nevada had negative equity exceeding 25% of their home’s value, as did 30% of
homeowners in Florida, 29% in Arizona, and 25% in California. First American
CoreLogic, Negative Equity Report (Aug. 13, 2009). Given the high median
home prices at the peak within these markets, a large percentage of these
homeowners are underwater by hundreds of thousands of dollars.
50
See, e.g., Deng & Quigley, supra note Error! Bookmark not
defined., at 3-4
Underwater and Not Walking Away
14
and psychological investments”) more than the market does.51
The “market value” of a home may be, for example, $198,000, but
it could be worth $355,000 to the homeowner – indeed why else
would they pay that much for it in the first place.52 Additionally,
homeowners as a class may be risk adverse, meaning that they
value the security of their good credit and of knowing they will not
suffer a deficiency judgment or a large tax bill (even if the risk of
either is low) over the money that they could save by defaulting.
Finally, homeowners as a class may value not having to move
more than they value the thousands they could save by walking
away and renting.53 As one economist has argued, “The so-called
underexercise of the default option, therefore, is actually rational
behavior without transaction costs....”54
This explanation naïvely – or deliberately - ignores much
of the cognitive sciences tell us about how humans actually make
decisions. As behavioral economists understand, humans make
decisions in ways that are less than fully rational – but are
understandable given the ways that humans (mis)perceive and
(mis)process information.
55
On a basic level, most humans have
difficulty doing mathematical calculations and are easily
overwhelmed, for example, by the variety of factors that one must
consider in deciding the financial benefits and costs of strategically
defaulting.56
51
See Ross, infra note
Humans are also susceptible to what behavioral
economists call the status quo bias – or the tendency to keep one’s
70, at 9 (noting “individuals had made large
financial, emotional, and psychological investments in their home.”)
52
See Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get it so Wrong, N.Y.
TIMES, September 2, 2009 (discussing a general belief among neoclassical
economists “that bubbles just don’t happen” and quoting Eugene Fama, “the
father of the efficient-market hypothesis,” as follows: “the word ‘bubble’ drives
me nuts... Housing markets are less liquid, but people are very careful when they
buy houses. It’s typically the biggest investment they’re going to make, so they
look around very carefully and they compare prices. The bidding process is very
detailed.” ).
53
For support of such a suggestion, see Ross, infra note 70, at 10
(discussing the ontologicial security of homeownership, arguing that “the home
offer[s] individuals a sense of order, continuity, and place or physical
belonging.”)
54
Kerry D. Vandell, Handing Over the Keys: A Perspective on
Mortgage Default Research, 21 J. AM. REAL ESTATE & URBAN ECON. ASS’N
211, 236 (1993).
55
See e.g., Bar-Gill, supra note 46, at 40 (discussing the affects of
human limitations on attention, memory, and processing ability which lead to
less than rational decisions, such as simply ignoring critical details in mortgage
contracts, when confronted with complex calculations).
56
See e.g., Ubel, supra note 3 (positing that human nature when
confronted with financial decisions involving detailed mathematics is to
disregard legitimate financial fears and follow the advice of others, such as real
estate agents).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
15
head in the sand.57 This bias means that even those humans who
could do complex calculations if they wanted to, usually don’t.
Moreover, humans suffer from other cognitive biases such as
myopia, or the tendency to overvalue up-front cost and undervalue
long-term gain.58
Additionally, like all human beings, homeowners suffer
from selective perception,
Thus, most underwater homeowners may fail to
cognitively grasp the full benefit of strategic default.
59
which causes them to fail to see
evidence – such as actual prices of sold homes in their
neighborhood – that would suggest a steep fall in their home’s
value.60 Instead, they see contrary indicators such as the list prices
of overpriced homes in their neighborhood, which taken out of
context suggest that prices have not fallen significantly. Selective
perception also causes homeowners to fail to attend to estimates on
websites such Zillow.com or fhfa.gov that show their home’s
declining value and to discount media reports of step price declines
as somehow inapplicable to their unique home, or their special
neighborhood.61 Relatedly, homeowners tend toward optimistic
overconfidence,62 – believing, for example, that home prices will
bounce back in a few years and that their homes will soon be worth
more than they paid.63
57
William Samuelson & Richard Zeckhauser, Status Quo Bias in
Decision Making, 1 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 7 (1988); see also Mario J. Rizzo
& Douglas Glen Whitman, Little Brother is Watching You: New Paternalism on
the Slippery Slopes, 51 ARIZ. L. REV 685, 686 (2009).
Indeed, selective perception may have
caused many homebuyers to ignore signs of the impending housing
market collapse in the first place - and optimistic overconfidence
may have caused many homeowners to take out interest-only
ARMs in the misplaced belief that they would have better salaries
58
See R.H. Strotz, Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility
Maximization, 23 REV. ECON. STUD. 165 (1955-56); Lester C. Thurow, Cash
Versus In-Kind Transfers, 64 AM. ECON. REV. 190 (1974); see also Barak Y.
Orbach, Unwelcome Benefits: Why Welfare Beneficiaries Reject Government
Aid, 24 LAW & INEQ. 107, 122 (2006).
59
Ubel, supra note 3 (labeling the human susceptibility to selective
perception as “unrealistic optimism”).
60
See Housing Over-Confidence, INVESTORS CHRON., Apr. 27, 2009
(noting, “On hearing that a neighbour's house has sold for a low price, our
reaction is often: ‘But our house is much more presentable than theirs.’
Everyone thinks they are Sarah Beeny. But they are not.”)
61
Id. (discussing the fact that, due to optimistic overconfidence, sellers
generally fail to adequately take price declines into account when setting list
prices.”)
62
Ubel, supra note 3 (noting that due to “unrealistic optimism”
homeowners over-estimated the future growth of their salaries and home
values).
63
An analogy here would be the reluctance of many investors to sell a
share that drops significantly in value after they bought it and wait in hopes that
the share will climb back up to the initial purchase price – even though there
may be little hope of it doing so.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
16
in a few years, or would refinance as their home’s value grew
exponentially.64
There is certainly much in this behavioral economic
account that helps explain the choices of underwater homeowners.
Many homeowners do tend to overvalue their homes, particularly
if they bought them during booms.
65
Many homeowners also have
their head in the sand, preferring to focus on things that they
believe they can control rather than things that they believe they
cannot.66
On the other hand, labeling the status quo bias, selective
perception, and optimistic overconfidence as “cognitive biases,”
doesn’t account for the way in which emotions unconsciously
color the perceptions of individuals who want, or need, to believe
something – including, for example, that their house is worth what
they paid.
67
As a large body of work in the neurosciences has
revealed, much of what passes for cognitive bias is actually
emotional bias, reached with no cognitive process whatsoever.68
64
See Housing Over-Confidence, supra note 59 (discussing distorting
effect on prices of the irrational belief that house prices would continue to rise.)
65
See Id. (noting that: “The average person over-estimates the price of
their house by between five and ten per cent. But there's variation around this
average. Whereas people who bought in recessions tend to value their houses
accurately, those who bought in booms are even more over-optimistic,
overvaluing their properties by up to 20 per cent.” And further explaining that:
“There are strong cognitive biases causing this - and not just plain wishful
thinking. One is the availability heuristic effect. If your biggest exposure to
housing market economics came when you bought during a boom - and of
course, many more people buy in booms than slumps - rapid house price
appreciation will loom large in your mind. This will cause you to over-estimate
its size and frequency, and so over-estimate your own house price.”)
66
If one accepts that homeowner decisions are the result of cognitive
biases, the solution to helping homeowners make better decisions – should
policy makers or others actually wish to encourage rational economic behavior
by underwater homeowners – is to help homeowners think better. This means
providing better information, helping homeowners calculate the benefits and
costs of default, and pointing out the cognitive biases that cloud their thinking.
Under this line of thinking, homeowners just need a little help in order to behave
more rationally.
67
See Christopher Merkle, Emotion and Finance - An Interdisciplinary
Approach to the Impact of Emotions on Financial Decision Making 14-15
(Working Paper, Feb. 28, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1097131
(“feelings act as a selective attentional filter for incoming stimuli. The strong
immediate experience of emotion may lead to a crowding out of other goals.
Secondly emotion influences the retrieval of information and knowledge from
memory.”). See also Zajonc at 157.
68
See e.g., Ralph D. Ellis & Natika Newton, Introduction
(summarizing collected papers addressing influence of emotion on perception),
in CONSCIOUSNESS & EMOTION: AGENCY, CONSCIOUS CHOICE, AND SELECTIVE
PERCEPTION ix, x-xi (Ralph D. Ellis & Natika Newton eds., 2005); R.B. Zajonc,
Feeling and Thinking: Preferences Need No Inferences, 35 AM. PSYCHOLOGIST
151, 155 (1980); John A. Bargh and Tanya L. Chartrand, The Unbearable
Underwater and Not Walking Away
17
In other words, when one is consciously or unconsciously
motivated to reach a certain conclusion, the brain’s emotion
systems focus awareness on information that is congruent with
one’s emotional need and directs the conscious to ignore,
reinterpret, or discount incongruent information.69 As such, if a
homeowner is not emotionally receptive to the idea that their home
is worth thousands less than they paid, it may be next-to-
impossible to convince him that he is underwater in the first place,
much less that it will take 20 years just to recover lost equity.70
Similarly, if a homeowner places great emotional stock in his
credit score, it may be futile to try to convince him that a few years
of a poor credit is not a big deal. Indeed, trying to persuade the
homeowner that he is wrong is likely to make him stick even more
firmly to his prior beliefs.71
Thus, if one is to understand how homeowners think, one
must understand how they feel. Most mortgage default risk
modeling fundamentally fails to appreciate this point and more
generally does not account for the primacy of emotion in driving
human behavior and decision-making. This may not matter if the
goal is to merely describe or model observable human behavior,
but it does matter to the extent that policymakers and others are
interested in encouraging individuals to make different choices –
Automaticity of Being, 54 AM. PSYCHOLOGIST 7 (1999). See also, David P.
Redlawsk, Motivated Reasoning, Affect, and the Role of Memory in Voter
Decision Making, in FEELING POLITICS: EMOTION IN POLITICAL INFORMATION
PROCESSING (David P. Redlawsk ed., 2006); (noting that “Emotion “may
indeed, be the primary vehicle implicated in motivated reasoning, leading to
selective attention, information distortions, and recall biases.”); Merkle, supra
note 64 (“Attention is focused on aspects of a situation that are consistent with
the prevailing emotion, what may result in different estimations of probabilities
for certain events or a different rating of an alternative’s global attractiveness.”);
Terry Maroney, Law and Emotion: A Proposed Taxonomy of an Emerging
Field, 30 (2) LAW AND HUMAN BEHAVIOR 119 (2006) (noting that, “First,
emotion can influence both which stimuli are perceived and how they are
perceived. This is first seen through the mechanism of attention. Because
emotionally salient stimuli tend to be the ones of greatest significance to one's
thriving, they will be attended to disproportionately.”).
69
See Milton Lodge, Charles Taber & Christopher Weber, First Steps
Toward a Dual-Process Accessibility Model of Political Beliefs, Attitudes, and
Behavior, in FEELING POLITICS, supra note 66.
70
Lauren Ross, The Internal Costs of Foreclosure 38, August 31, 2009
(unpublished thesis) (on file with author) (noting that “[m]any individuals are
reluctant to acknowledge that the housing and mortgage markets have
significantly changed and are no longer wholly sustainable or lucrative
investments.”).
71
David P. Redlawsk, Feeling Politics: New Research into Emotion and
Politics, in FEELING POLITICS, supra note [x], at 1 (explaining that individuals
often end up feeling stronger than they did before being confronted with
information that would have been expected, under rational models of belief
formation, to cause them to reassess their existing beliefs).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
18
or to continue to make the same choices for that matter. In most
studies of homeowner decision-making, however, emotions are
treated as an x-factor to be calculated around in figuring out how
other varying factors affect individual choice and market
behavior.72 Emotion is rarely considered in and of itself as a
primary factor motivating both people and markets. For example,
default risk analysts have studied the relationships between initial
loan-to-value and mortgage default,73 current equity and mortgage
default, affordability and mortgage default,74 credit scores and
mortgage default,75 geography and mortgage default,76 and
unemployment and mortgage default77 – to name a few. But
researchers have shown little interest in the relationship between
guilt and mortgage default.78
The neglect of emotion is particularly intriguing given the
recent work of Luigi Guiso, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales,
which found that 81% of homeowners believe that it is immoral to
default on a mortgage, and that homeowners who hold this attitude
are 77% less likely to declare their intention to default than those
who do not.
Nor have they shown any interest in
the relationship between fear and mortgage default.
79
72
See Vandell, infra note 165, at 236 (pricing models “all assumed
ruthless default whenever the value of the mortgage dropped below the value of
the property” and ignored “psychological costs.”); and See Foote, et. al., supra
note 14 at 5 (explaining that in their default prediction model the probability of
default, guilt, shame, and reduced access to future credit were calculated around:
“We assume that the decision to default costs the borrower some amount !"#$%!
period, which can be interpreted as some combination of guilt, shame, and
reduced access to future credit.”)
Indeed, once the equity shortfall exceeds 10% of a
home’s value, the study found that “moral and social
considerations” are the “most important variables predicting
73
Yongheng Deng, John M. Quigley, & Robert Van Order, Mortgage
Terminations, Heterogeneity and the Exercise of Mortgage Options,
ECONOMETRICA 275 (2000) (showing that higher default risk is related to higher
initial LTV’s).
74
See Foote, et. al., supra note 14 at 3-13.
75
Satjajit Chatterjee, Dean Corbai, & José Victor Ríos-Rull, Credit
Scoring and Competitive Pricing of Default Risk (unpublished and incomplete,
Jan. 2007), available at http://pier.econ.upenn.edu/Events/scorevictor.pdf.
76
Deng, Quigley, & Van Order, supra note 71 at 23.
77
Id. at 17 (finding that trigger events, such as unemployment and
divorce have significant impact on homeowners’ exercise of the default option).
78
While it may seem obvious that one who feels guilty about the idea
of defaulting will be less likely to do so, it is equally obvious that those with
high loan-to-value ratios, the unemployed, and individuals with low credit
scores will be more likely to default. But economists study these things anyway
in order to determine how much they matter and how predictive they are of
mortgage default. Such information is used by economists to assist lenders in
assessing risk and pricing mortgages, but it also informs public policy by
purporting to illuminate the most efficient ways to reduce foreclosures.
79
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 21.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
19
strategic default.”80 So strong are these variables, in fact, that only
17% of homeowners indicted that they would default if the equity
shortfall reached 50%.81 On the other hand, the study found that
people who know someone who has strategically defaulted are
82% more likely to declare their intention to do so.82 The authors
thus caution that “a policy aimed at helping people in arrears with
their mortgage could have devastating effects on the incentives to
strategically default of people who can afford to pay their
mortgage if it is perceived to bail out people unjustly and thus
undermine the moral commitment to pay.”83
While the study sheds important light on the role of social
and moral constraints in the default decision, its conclusion also
highlights the problem with crafting public policy from studies that
do not try to understand why people act the way that they do.
Perhaps the authors are right--perhaps people will respond to loan
modification programs for those who can no longer afford their
mortgages by defaulting on their own mortgages--but there is no
evidence to suggest that this is the case. One might just as easily
assert that the failure of banks to modify loans for individuals in
need, while banks themselves have been bailed out by the federal
government, will cause individuals to conclude that they should
forget about morals and just look out for their own self-interests.
84
In order to know whether either of these assertions is true, one
needs to understand how moral beliefs and attitudes are formed,
and one needs to understand how humans make decisions. And, as
evidence from the cognitive sciences convincingly demonstrates,
emotion is primary to both.85
The Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales article does however
confirm something that policy makers and lenders already know
80
Id. at 21-22.
81
Id. at 15.
82
Id. at 6.
83
Id. at 3. Indeed, one thrust of the paper is that the Obama
administration’s plan to encourage modification of loans to make them more
affordable is misguided - and likely to backfire. Id. at 21.
84
For an example of one individual who feels this way, see the web
posting of L. Serbanescu at Economist.com, available at
http://www.economist.com/businessfinance/displayStory.cfm?story_id=139055
02&mode=comment&#commentStartPosition (writing that “[t]he financial
system created the house market bubble, putting everyone that wanted a house
in the uncomfortable position of paying inflated prices. The financial
establishment made tons of money in the process....Now that ditching a
mortgage makes economic sense for a homeowner, The Economist discovers
that such behavior is immoral…Why should anyone be morally obliged to
continue to pay them at a loss?”).
85
R.B. Zajonc, Feeling and Thinking: Preferences Need No
Inferences, 35 AM. PSYCHOLOGIST 151, 155 (1980); John A. Bargh and Tanya
L. Chartrand, The Unbearable Automaticity of Being, 54 AM. PSYCHOLOGIST 7
(1999).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
20
and use to their advantage: people are less likely to default if
doing so will make them feel like immoral or irresponsible persons
– and are especially unlikely to default if they believe others will
think of them as immoral or irresponsible persons.86 Guilt and
shame are powerful motivators,87 and there is no doubt that many
people who have faced foreclosure feel a great deal of both.88
As Linda, a single mom in Tampa who asked that her last
name not be used, explained, "As a mom, I feel like I let my
children down… It's a terrible embarrassment, and it's
humiliating.”
89
Linda is not alone: a recent qualitative sociological
study of the internal costs of foreclosure found that feelings of
personal failure, shame, and embarrassment dominated the
accounts of individuals who had lost their homes to foreclosure.90
Moreover, such feelings predominated even when individuals were
not at fault for their predicament, but were victims of the declining
economy and/or unethical practices by mortgage brokers.91
86
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 8 (stating that “[m]oral considerations,
if widespread, may strongly mitigate the likelihood that American households
will default on their mortgage”). Research in social psychology has shown that
humans invest significant emotional stake in “face” – or their “claimed identity
as a competent, intelligent, or moral persons” - and will go to great lengths to
avoid actions which publically threaten this identity. See Holley S. Hodgins &
Elizabeth Liebeskind, Apology Versus Defense: Antecedents and Consequences,
39 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL. 297, 297 (2003).
And,
87
See Danielle Einstein and Kevin Lanning, Shame, Guilt, Ego
Development, and the five-factor model of personality, 66 JOURNAL OF
PERSONALITY 555 (1998) (explaining that guilt and shame are negative affective
states which act as moral voices guiding social activity of individuals).
88
See Ross, supra note 68 (“The notion of guilt ascription was also
central to these findings. Although many individuals recounted the exact ways in
which they were “misled” in their loan negotiations, they often returned to the
idea of being personally responsible for their actions.”).
89
Judi Hasson, Homeowners Who Just Walk Away, MSN MONEY,
http://articles.moneycentral.msn.com/Banking/HomeFinancing/HomeownersWh
oJustWalkAway.aspx (last visited Oct. 9, 2009).
90
See Ross, supra note 68, at 37
91
See id. at 35. One woman in the study described her sense of
“utmost responsibility to make her monthly payments on time” as follows:
I made a commitment to pay my loan and I want to pay my
loan. I’m a hard working person and I want to make good on
my loan, but there’s no way I possibly can in the situation the
economy’s in right now.
Others expressed concern over being perceived as “irresponsible
citizens’ or “burdens on society:”
And um so I’m just, I’m kind of interested in the public
perception. You know I don’t want to be a burden on the rest
of society because I’m not paying my mortgage. Now there’s
Underwater and Not Walking Away
21
as further evidence of the shame and guilt felt by those who
experience foreclosure, large damage awards for humiliation are
common features of successful suits against lenders for wrongful
foreclosure.92
While no study to date has sought to quantify the role of the
desire to avoid guilt and shame in underwater homeowners’
decisions not to strategically default, more general studies on the
role of guilt and shame in motivating human behavior suggest a
significant impact.
93
this big giant bailout and I’m involved in that. You know, my
mortgage was one of the mortgages not being paid.
The desire to avoid guilt and shame cannot,
however, completely explain the reluctance of homeowners to
92
See, e.g., Levine v. First Nat. Bank of Commerce, 917 So.2d 1235,
05-106 (La.App. 5 Cir. 2005) (holding “evidence was sufficient to support
award to mortgagor of $150,000 for humiliation and embarrassment and
$150,000 for mental anguish); Clark v. West, 395 S.E.2d 884 (Ga.App., 1990)
(holding “[m]ortgagor's obtaining cancellation of foreclosure sale in equitable
action did not bar her from pursuing separate claim of damages for humiliation
and emotional distress for the alleged intentional, wrongful foreclosure by
mortgagees); Carter v. Countrywide Home Loans, 2009 WL 1010851 (E.D.Va.
2009) (allowing claims for “humiliation and damage to reputation” due to
wrongful foreclosure under the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act
(“RESPA”), 12 U.S.C. § 2601 et seq., and the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act
(“FDCPA”), 15 U.S.C. § 1692 et seq.,); Mason v. Chase Bank of Texas, N.A.,
2008 WL 3412212 (Tex.App.-Dallas 2008) (claim for humiliation from
attempted foreclosure); Brannon v. Bridge Capital Corp., 2008 WL 2225791
(M.D.Ala., 2008) (discussing plaintiff claim that “foreclosure publishings
caused him embarrassment and humiliation); Lee v. Javitch, Block & Rathbone,
LLP, 2008 WL 1886178 (S.D.Ohio 2008) (humiliation from wrongful
foreclosure recoverable under the FDCPA); Cushing & Dolan, PC v. National
Lenders, Inc., 2004 WL 2712208 (Mass.Super., 2004) (claim for “humiliation”
due to “public notices of foreclosure on their home and the inspection of their
home by potential buyers, lawyers, and auctioneers.”); Volk v. Wisconsin
Mortg. Assur. Co., 474 N.W.2d 40 (N.D. 1991) (claiming damage to plaintiffs
“personal reputation, credit rating, financial reputation, unfavorable publicity,
embarrassment, humiliation, and ridicule caused by the foreclosure action.”);
and Union Federal Sav. Bank v. Hale, 1993 WL 488399 (Ohio App. 9 Dist.
1993) (defendant in foreclosure action averring that “as a result of Plaintiff's
wrongful refusal to accept the aforementioned mortgage payments, I have
suffered damage to my credit rating and reputation; emotional distress, anxiety,
embarrassment, humiliation and worry….”).
93
See e.g., CARROLL E. IZARD, HUMAN EMOTIONS, (New York:
Plenum 1977)(explaining that guilt is the primary motivational factor in a
mature conscience); Dwight Merunka , et. al., Modeling and Measuring the
Impact of Fear, Guilt and Shame Appeals on Persuasion for Health
Communication: a Study of Anti-Alcohol Messages, Working paper
(2009)(finding that “Shame motives social behavior and leads to conformity to
social norms.”); and Damien Arthur and Pascale Quester, Who’s Afraid of that
Ad? Applying Segmentation to the Protection Motivation Mode, 21
PSYCHOLOGY AND MARKETING 671 (2004) (demonstrating the importance of
fear, guilt, and shame in determining behavior).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
22
default. Indeed, the Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales study found
that only 41% of individuals who no moral issue with strategic
default would strategically default at $100,000 in negative
equity.94 The question is thus: what keeps the other 59% from
walking? Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales theorize that even amoral
people may be deterred from defaulting by the social stigma that
comes with foreclosure.95 They are probably right – up to a point.
But their study did not actually ask these “amoral” individuals
what keeps them from walking. At some point – if not $100,000
then $200,000 (where 41% of the “amoral” individuals still would
not walk)96
Moreover, foreclosure rates are considerably lower than
would be suggested by the Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales study, as
the percentage of people who actually default is much lower than
the percentage that indicated they would default in the survey,
moral qualms or not. For example, the study found that 26% of
individuals would default at $100,000 in negative equity and 41%
would do so at $200,000.
- social stigma alone becomes an unconvincing
explanation.
97
The voices of those who have actually faced foreclosure
suggest another powerful emotion that may be keeping
homeowners from defaulting: fear. Indeed, the term commonly
used to describe foreclosure by those who face it is “terrifying.”
But given the number of homeowners
that are significantly underwater, one would expect foreclosure
rates should be higher if this were the case.
98
As one commentator on foreclosure has noted, “foreclosure is that
terrifying word no homeowner ever wants to hear, let alone
experience.”99
94
Guiso et al., supra note
People not only fear losing their homes, but fear
having ruined credit for life, not be able to find a decent place to
live, to buy a car, to get a credit card, to get insurance, to ever buy
a house, or even get a job. Foreclosure is seen as the end of life as
11, at 10.
95
Id. at 8.
96
Id. at 17.
97
Id. at 17.
98
John Leland, Facing Default, Some Walk Out on New Homes, N.Y.
TIMES, Feb. 29, 2008 (homeowner reporting being “terrified” by foreclosure);
Las Vegas Military Wife Fights to Save Home, LAS VEGAS NOW
http://www.lasvegasnow.com/Global/story.asp?S=10965954 (describing
“terrifying” fight to save home); and Chris Isidore, Homes in Foreclosure Top 1
Million, CNNMONEY, June 5, 2008,
http://money.cnn.com/2008/06/05/news/economy/foreclosure/index.htm?postver
sion=2008060510 (describing foreclosure as terrifying).
99
See Jenny Greenleaf, About Foreclosure Law, eHow,
http://www.ehow.com/about_4571547_foreclosure-law.html (last visited Oct. 9,
2009) (noting, “Foreclosure is that terrifying word no homeowner ever wants to
hear, let alone experience”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
23
one knows it: financial suicide to be avoided at all costs.100 In
short, fear – like shame and guilt - is a powerful motivator in
homeowner decisions not to default.101
Further empirical study is necessary to qualify the
statistical significance of shame, guilt, and fear in homeowner
decisions to strategic default. But all three play a critical role in
motivating human behavior and deserve further academic study in
the mortgage default context.
102
Academics and non-academics
alike, however, intuitively understand the power of these emotions
to control human behavior. As such, those who benefit from
underwater homeowner decisions not to default have not waited to
for statistical proof of the efficacy of those emotions to cultivate
them.103
V. The Social Control of the Housing Crisis
A concern repeatedly voiced by policy makers, economists,
and the media is that the “social pressure not to default will
weaken” to the point homeowners will begin to walk in droves.104
100
Of course, to argue that homeowner decisions not to default are
motivated by fear is not to suggest that cognitive biases play no role. The two
are not mutually exclusive – but are mutually reinforcing. Much homeowner
fear is driven by the misperception or overestimation of the future costs
associated with foreclosure – and this fear in turn leads to further selective
perception and/or wishful thinking about the probability of housing prices
returning to previous levels.
Of particular concern is the contagion effect, the notion that once a
101
See e.g., Damien Arthur and Pascale Quester, 2004, Who’s Afraid of
that Ad? Applying Segmentation to the Protection Motivation Mode, 21
Psychology and Marketing 671 (2004) (confirming the positive relationship
between fear and persuasion); Michael S. LaTour and Herbert J. Rotfeld, There
are Threats and (May be) Fear-Caused Arousal: Theory and Confusions of
Appeals to Fear and Fear Arousal Itself, 26 JOURNAL OF ADVERTISING
45(1997)(confirming that fear motivates behavior); Irving L. Janis and Seymour
Freshbach, Effects of Fear-Arousing Communications 48 JOURNAL OF
ABNORMAL AND SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY 78 (1953) (finding that fear appeals
influence attitudes and behavior).
102
For studies of the role of guilt, shame and fear in motivating
behavior in other contexts, see e.g., Damien Arthur and Pascale Quester, supra
note 97 (demonstrating the power of negative emotions of fear, guilt, and shame
in marketing) and Ken Chapman, Fear Appeal Research: Perspectives and
Application, 3 AMERICAN MARKETING ASSOCIATION SUMMER EDUCATOR’S
CONFERENCE PROCEEDINGS 1 (1992) (finding that that negative emotional
responses significantly influences individual behavior)
103
See Rashmi Dyal-Chand, Human Worth as Collateral, 38 RUTGERS
L.J. 793 (2007) (noting “[c]redit card lenders, on the other hand, do seem to
recognize the power of shaming their borrowers, though they may not explicitly
describe it as such”).
104
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 22; Id. at 2 (reporting that “strategic
defaults may produce contagion effects”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
24
few people in a neighborhood walk, others will follow, until whole
neighborhoods end up as empty wastelands.105 Indeed,
geographical patterns already show that foreclosures cluster in
neighborhoods,106
Alarmed by the possibility that foreclosures may reach a
tipping point, formal federal policy has aimed to stem the tide of
foreclosures through programs designed to “reduce household cash
flow problems,” such as the Making Home Affordable (MHA)
loan modification program
suggesting that once foreclosure is seen as
acceptable within a given community, and an individual knows
others who have survived foreclosure, there may be less reason to
feel ashamed of one’s decision to walk or to fear the consequences.
107
and Hope For Homeowners.108
Implicit in this approach is the assumption that home owners are
unlikely to default on their mortgage if they can “afford”109 the
monthly payment. In other words, federal policy assumes that
homeowners are – for the most part - not “ruthless” and won’t
walk away from their mortgages simply because they have
negative equity.110
105
Guiso et al., supra note
Most homeowners walk only when they can no
longer afford to stay. As evidence of this fact, only 45% of
homeowners would walk even if they had $300,000 in negative
11, at 20; John P. Harding, Eric Rosenblatt,
& Vincent W. Yao, The Contagion Effect of Foreclosed Properties, J. OF URB.
ECON. 21 (2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1160354 (noting that
“nearby distressed property has a significant, negative effect on the prices of
nearby homes over and above the overall trend in market prices”).
106
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 6.
107
See Making Home Affordable,
http://makinghomeaffordable.gov/about.html (last visited Oct. 9, 2009)
(explaining that the Making Home Affordable program aims “to strengthen the
national economy by providing homeowners whose homes have decreased in
value, thereby inhibiting their ability to refinance to a lower rate within the
private sector, with a more affordable monthly option for their mortgage
payments….”).
108
See Hope for Homeowners,,
http://www.hud.gov/hopeforhomeowners/ (last visited Oct. 9, 2009). The
HOPE website describes the program as follows:
Under the program, borrowers having difficulty paying their
mortgages will be eligible to refinance into FHA-insured
mortgages they can afford. For borrowers who refinance under
HOPE for Homeowners, lenders will be required to "write
down" the size of the mortgage to a maximum of 90 percent of
the home's new appraised value.
109
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 19.
110
See ROBERT AVERY ET. AL., CREDIT RISK, CREDIT SCORING, AND
THE PERFORMANCE OF HOME MORTGAGES (1996), available at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/1996/796lead.pdf (noting that
credit risk models reflect fact that few borrowers are “ruthless”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
25
equity. 111 This percentage drops to 38% among the subset of
individuals who believe it is immoral to strategically default on
one’s mortgage (a subset to which 87% of homeowners belong).112
These numbers suggest that the “moral constraint” is a
powerful one indeed – and that, for most people, only the complete
inability to afford their mortgage would push them to default. On
the other hand, the fact that 63% of “amoral” individuals would
default at $300,000 in negative equity, and 59% would do so at
$200,000,
113
This is not to say that there is a grand scheme to manipulate
the emotions of homeowners, or even that the government and
other institutions consciously cultivate these emotional constraints
on default.
suggests that federal policy can only proceed on the
premise that affordability is the prime consideration as long as the
moral and social constraints on foreclosure remain strong. The
government thus has an incentive, along with certain other
economic and social institutions interested in limiting the number
of foreclosures, in cultivating guilt and shame in those who would
contemplate walking away. Similarly, knowing that guilt and
shame alone are not enough to prevent many individuals from
defaulting once negative equity is extreme, these same institutions
have an interest in increasing the perceived cost of foreclosure by
cultivating fear of financial disaster for those who contemplate it.
114
But, to be sure, the predominate message of
political, social, and economic institutions in the United States has
functioned to cultivate fear, shame, and guilt in those who might
contemplate foreclosure. These emotions in turn function as a
form of internalized social control –encouraging conformity to the
norm of meeting one’s mortgage obligations as long as one can
afford to do so.115
The clear message to American homeowners from nearly
all fronts is that one has a moral responsibility to pay one’s
mortgage. The message is conveyed not only by political, social,
and economic institutions, but by the majority of Americans who
believe that voluntarily defaulting on a mortgage is immoral. At
the political level, government spokespersons, including President
Obama, have repeatedly emphasized the virtue of homeowners
who have acted “responsibly” in “making their payments each
111
See generally Guiso et al., supra note 11.
112
Id.
113
GUISO ET AL., supra note 11, at 10.
114
Social control is defined by most contemporary scholars “as
attempts, whether intentional or not, by the state or social institutions to regulate
or encourage conformity to a set or norms through socialization or the threat of
coercion, or both,” David Pearce Demers and K. Viswanath, MASS MEDIA,
SOCIAL CONTROL, AND SOCIAL CHANGE 9 (1998)
115
Id. (noting that social control is most effective when “external
control comes to be incorporated into the personality of the individual.”)
Underwater and Not Walking Away
26
month”116 and have lamented the erosion of “our common values”
by, for example, those who irresponsibly borrowed beyond their
means.117 The worst criticism has been reserved, however, for
those who would walk away from mortgages that they can afford.
Typical of such criticism is that of Secretary of the Treasury Henry
Paulson, who declared in a televised speech: “And let me
emphasize, any homeowner who can afford his mortgage payment
but chooses to walk away from an underwater property is simply a
speculator – and one who is not honoring his obligations.”118
Paulson’s comment is mild, however, compared to the
media invective toward those who strategically walk from their
mortgages. Such individuals are portrayed as obscene,
119
offensive,120 and unethical,121 and likened to deadbeat dads who
walk out on their children,122 or those who would have “given up”
and just handed over Europe to the Nazis.123
There is similarly no shortage of moralizing about the
responsibilities of mortgagors. Typical media messages include:
"we need a culture of responsible consumers and homeowners;"
124
116
President Barack Obama, Foreclosure Speech: Housing Plan, (Feb.
18, 2009), available at
http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/02/18/obama-
foreclosure-speech_n_167889.html
117
Id.
118
Secretary Henry M. Paulson, Jr., U.S. Housing and Mortgage
Market Update before the National Association of Business Economists (Mar. 3,
2008), http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/hp856.htm.
119
Fox Business: Some Homeowners Who Can’t Pay Choosing to Just
Walk Away (Fox Business television broadcast Feb. 19, 2009), available at
http://www.foxbusiness.com/video/index.html?playerId=videolandingpage&stre
amingFormat=FLASH&referralObject=3644995&referralPlaylistId=1292d14d0
e3afdcf0b31500afefb92724c08f046 [hereinafter “Fox Business”]. (“Seems
obscene. Everyone else in the country is trying to pay their mortgages and
trying to get things done. They realize in many cases they are underwater that
their mortgage is worth more than their home. If you have obnoxious kids, walk
away from your kids. Seems weird. Doesn’t it?”)
120
Id. (“I know you are not looking at the ethics of this; you are a good
and savvy businessman. Do you find it even a tinge offensive that we are
moving away from personal responsibility? If we can’t hack it we bail out of
it.”)
121
The Mike Gallagher National Radio Show, Youwalkaway.com
(Townhall, May 1, 2009).
122
Fox Business, supra note 115.
123
Id. (“And you know when you enter into an agreement and
everyone just throws up the keys and says you know it’s really tough this month,
it’s gonna be tough next month, declining real estate values, we are just going to
quit. Can you imagine if we all did that going into World War II? The
Japanese just kicked our butts at Pearl Harbor, the odds are overwhelming, the
Germans have just taken over Europe, and we just quit. What would happen if
we all quit? Let’s just cease and desist.”)
124
Economy: Why Not Just Walk Away From A Home? (NPR radio
broadcast Feb. 13, 2008) available at
Underwater and Not Walking Away
27
“one should always honor financial obligations;125 “when you
enter into a contract that should mean something;”126 “there was a
time when people felt really bad about not paying back debt,” 127
and, “money is more than a matter of numbers. There are ethics
involved. Most people feel, or should feel, an obligation to pay
their debts.”128 Even sympathy for those who default because of
predatory lending is frequently lacking: “We’ve read too many sob
stories in the press about ‘predatory lending’ — a rare,
misunderstood, and vastly exaggerated phenomenon. It’s time for
the poster children for irresponsibility to get some face time.”129
Indeed, a homeowner contemplating a strategic default
would be hard pressed to avoid the message that doing so would
place them among the most despicable members of society. It is
thus not surprising that a large number of media stories about
individuals who walk on their mortgages indicate that these
individuals ask that their “last name not be used” to protect their
privacy.
130
Nobody wants to be indentified as a deadbeat – or, as
one commentator describes them, “a blight on our society."131
http://www.npr.org/templates/story/story.php?storyId=18958049
Such individuals seek to protect their privacy for good reason, as it
is not just the media and the government that acts as norm
enforcers, but also individuals – as can be seen in the frequent
railings on internet comment boards and blogs about strategic
defaulters. In one typical example, “Bob Green”, an individual
enraged by the story of “Raam” who posted his own story of why
he strategically defaulted on his mortgage, wrote: “Amazing.
Simply amazing. The types of speculators like ‘Raam’ and others
should be tied to a tree and left to rot. It’s these fine people who
are going to walk away and leave the societal, writ large, on the
[hereinafter
“NPR”].
125
Id.
126
Fox Business, supra note 119.
127
60 Minutes: The U.S. Mortgage Meltdown (CBS television
broadcast May 25, 2008), available at
http://www.cbsnews.com/video/watch/?id=4126094n&tag=related;photovideo.
128
Weston, supra note 2.
129
Steven Spruiell, Obama Pays Bail Money, NATIONAL REVIEW
ONLINE, June 12, 2008,
http://article.nationalreview.com/?q=OWJkNGE3ZjIyYTAzOTg0MWJlYmViM
2FlZGVjMjY4ZmY= [hereinafter “National Review”].
130
Weston, supra note 128, at 3.
131
Brian Eckhouse, Whether to Walk Away: Housing’s Moral
Minefield, LAS VEGAS SUN, Mar. 22, 2009,
http://www.lasvegassun.com/news/2009/mar/22/whether-walk-away-housings-
moral-minefield/
Underwater and Not Walking Away
28
hook for their problems. Good job Raam–way to take
responsibility.” 132
Moreover, a homeowner who turned to any number of
credit counseling agencies would also find little sympathy - and
much moralizing - should they announce their plan to walk on their
“affordable” mortgage. Gail Cunningham of the National
Foundation for Credit Counseling declared for example in an
interview on NPR: “Walking away from one's home should be the
absolute last resort. However desperate a situation might become
for a homeowner, that does not relieve us of our
responsibilities."
133
132
Posting of Bob Green to
Indeed, the uniform message of both
governmental and non-profit counseling agencies (which are
http://www.mint.com/blog/finance-
core/should-you-walk-away-from-your-home/. “Raam” tells his story as
follows:
I purchased my first rental property at the age of 21. Everyone
said I would make a killing and was really smart for investing
so young. I wish I had done more research and seen that we
were approaching an inevitable bubble. I bought my first
property (a 2-family) for $190k in 2003. Within a year it was
valued at double that. After refinancing and putting money
into the first property, I bought two more properties the
following two years. I had 12 tenants total (being a landlord is
no easy task!). The mortgage lenders were pushing ARM’s
like crazy… and they made sense to an investor like me. I
needed the lowest monthly payment so I could take the little
income left from the rent to put back into the properties. Plus,
I could always just refinance my 2-year fixed / 28 year
adjustable mortgage before the 2 years-fixed were up
(refinance to a conventional 30-year fixed)… right? Well,
taxes went way up. I had a few tenants that cost me over $15k
in lost rent (damn tenant-rights laws!), unexpected property
damage from frozen water pipes, a couple more bad tenants,
and while all this was happening the value of my house
secretly dropped below the amount I owed… oh sh*t. Then I
get a letter in the mail saying my monthly mortgage payments
are going to increase by more than $600 a month… but wait,
I’m already dishing out over $200 a month from my pocket to
pay for the properties (assuming all the units are fully rented)!
I can’t refinance because the value of the property is less than
what I owe. I can bust my ass for the next 5-10 years trying to
keep up with the payments or I can let everything fall down,
file for bankruptcy, and move on. I’m filing. And I’m damn
glad. $450k multi-family properties are now for sale at
$140k… less than I bought my first property in 2003. For me
it’s easy because they were investment properties, not houses
my family lived in (I’m single). I’m renting now and saving as
much money as I can, because when things start to turn around
I want to be ready, not buried under a million dollars in debt.
Posting of “Raam” to: http://www.mint.com/blog/finance-
core/should-you-walk-away-from-your-home/.
133
NPR, supra note 124.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
29
typically funded at least in significant part by the financial
industry) is that “walking away” is not a responsible choice134 and
should be avoided at all costs.135
What makes this moral suasion so effective is that major
socializing agents in the United States tend to speak with one
voice. Thus, when the government, or the credit industry, tells
individuals that they have a responsibility to pay their mortgage
even if they are seriously underwater, the message is seen as
“echoing a deep-seated American belief that one should always
honor financial obligations,”
136
– and not as an effort to fix the
primary burden of the housing meltdown on homeowners rather
than the financial industry or the government. More critically,
because the media and non-profit consumer counseling agencies
promote the same message, the government and the financial
industry need not bear the primary burden of moral suasion – nor is
the message ever identified with those political and economic
institutions that have a vested interest in promoting “homeowner
responsibility.” The message rings true to the ear and, as such,
most homeowners question neither the content of the message, nor
its source.137
Social control of would be defaulters is not limited to moral
suasion, however. Predominate messages regarding foreclosure
also frequently employ fear to persuade homeowners that strategic
default is a bad choice:
134
See, e.g., Fannie May, Foreclosure Prevention FAQs (answering the
question “is it best to walk away from my property if I can no longer make the
payments?” as follows: “Walking away from your property is not a good choice.
Continue to live in your house as long as you are trying to get help from your
mortgage company or through a housing counselor.”). Available at
http://www.fanniemae.com/homeowners/frequently-asked-questions.html (last
visited Oct. 9, 2009)
135
HUD, How to Avoid Foreclosure,
http://www.hud.gov/offices/adm/hudclips/forms/files/pa426h.pdf (last visited
Oct. 15, 2009) (stressing to homeowners that “you should avoid foreclosure if
possible” and “[d]on’t lose your home and damage your credit history); see also
Anaheim Housing Counseling Agency,
http://www.anaheimhousingcounselingagency.org/id21.html (last visited Oct. 9,
2009) (“Losing your home can be the worst and most devastating event to you
personally, and your credit history. This is a scenario that you don’t want to
occur if you can avoid it.”); see also, Foreclosure Avoidance Counseling,
http://www.hud.gov/offices/hsg/sfh/hcc/fc/ (last visited Oct. 9, 2009) (“HUD-
approved housing counseling agencies are available to provide you with the
information and assistance you need to avoid foreclosure.”).
136
NPR, supra note 124 (quoting, Gail Cunningham, spokeswoman for
the National Foundation for Credit Counseling).
137
See JOHN O'SHAUGHNESSY & NICHOLAS JACKSON O'SHAUGHNESSY,
THE MARKETING POWER OF EMOTION 61 (2003) (explaining that individuals
tend to uncritically endorse information that in line with their affective
predispositions).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
30
What is real--and what is very much downplayed by
these outfits [like YouWalkAway.com] --is how
completely a foreclosure wrecks your finances.
Near term, you might get slammed with a massive
tax bill, since forgiven debt can be subject to
income tax. Long term, car loans and--you guessed
it--home loans will be much harder to come by.
How's that for walking away? This is the American
Dream ended in disaster". 138
Indeed, almost every media story on those who “walk away
from their mortgages” condemns the behavior as immoral and
enlists some “expert” to explain that foreclosure is, despite any
claims to the contrary, a devastating event:139
138
Barbara Kiviat, Walking Away From Your Mortgage, TIME, June 19,
2008 available at
http://www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,1816472,00.html (quoting
Odette Williamson, a foreclosure lawyer at the National Consumer Law Center).
139
See, e.g., Kiviat, supra note 138:
The whole idea of walking away is troubling to consumer
advocates, who worry that these firms are whitewashing the
fact that foreclosure is a traumatic experience--both financially
and emotionally--that takes years to recover from.”
And, Nightline: The Big Cut (ABC Television broadcast Jan. 31,
2008), available at
http://abcnews.go.com/Video/playerIndex?id=4220208&affil=wxyz :
The thing is you have to take into consideration here
is that this is a real disaster for your credit, if you have a
foreclosure on your record, even default. But if you fall
behind on your mortgage, and don’t pay it, everyone you go to
borrow money from for the next 6-7 years is going to know
about this. When you try to find a job, when you try to rent an
apartment, this is going to be on your credit. It’s not like you
walk away free, you walk away with a huge black mark on
your credit rating.”
See also John A. Schoen, Why It’s a Bad Idea to Walk Away From the
Mortgage, MSNBC, March 16, 2009,
http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/29669640// (editorializing that “[t]he most
important reason [why is a bad idea to walk away]: You signed a contract, took
the money and promised to pay the lender back. That’s what the law now
requires you to do”; and going on the explain that foreclosure will destroy your
credit”); Fox Business, supra note 119; Nightline, supra note 139; NPR, supra
note 124; Weston, supra note 2.; Santelli’s Tea Party (CNBC television
broadcast Feb. 19, 2009) available at,
http://www.cnbc.com/id/15840232?video=1039849853; Streitfeld, supra note
2; NATIONAL REVIEW, supra note 129; Can’t Pay, Won’t Pay, ECONOMIST, July
25, 2009,
Underwater and Not Walking Away
31
A single missed mortgage payment, says MSN
Money columnist and credit expert Liz Pulliam
Weston, knocks 100 points off your credit score.
Every missed payment thereafter compounds the
damage. A notice of default typically comes after
the third missed payment, delivering a knockout
blow to the homeowner's credit. … The direct effect
of any of these outcomes on credit scores is
dramatic, and it ripples through every corner of
borrowers' financial lives. The former homeowners
will be unable to get new credit at reasonable rates,
and issuers of their existing credit cards can raise
interest rates because they are considered greater
risks.140
Similar warnings of disaster pervade the information given
to homeowners by HUD-approved housing counseling agencies,
141
such as the following from the Anaheim Housing Counseling
Agency:
Losing your home can be the worst and most
devastating event to you personally, and your credit
history. This is a scenario that you don’t want to
occur if you can avoid it! Not only will you lose the
comfort of your home and your investment, but a
Foreclosure will stay pending on your credit history
for as long as 10 years. This will jeopardize your
ability to qualify for any future home loan
purchases, it may affect your ability to access loans
for car purchase and other needed purchases, and
http://www.economist.com/businessfinance/displayStory.cfm?story_id=139055
02.
140
HASSON, supra note 89.
141
Clearpoint Credit Counseling Solutions, Default and Foreclosure
Counseling,
http://www.bydesignsolutions.org/default_and_foreclosure_counseling.html
(last visited Oct. 10, 2009) (“For homeowners, the thought of losing your home
in a foreclosure is frightening. Your mortgage payment is usually your single
largest financial obligation.”); see also GreenPath Debt Solutions, Housing
Counseling, http://www.greenpath.com/how-we-can-help/housing-
counseling.htm (last visited Oct. 10, 2009) (“Greenpath’s housing counseling
services can help you preserve your most important asset, your home. After all,
tenants, homeowners and future home purchasers have a lot to lose if their
finances get out of control-and a lot to gain from housing counseling delivered
by an unbiased housing counselor.”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
32
loan costs are likely to be higher both in fees and
interest paid.142
As discussed above, fear alone is a powerful motivator. But
guilt and fear in combination are even more potent.143
As explored above, however, there is in fact a huge
financial upside to strategic default for seriously underwater
homeowners – an upside that is routinely ignored by the media,
credit counseling agencies, and other political and economic
institutions in “informing” homeowners about the consequences of
This may
be because most individuals have a deep-seated, if ill-defined,
sense that if they do “bad things,” bad things will happen to them.
Whatever the psychological underpinnings, most people simply do
not believe they will escape punishment for their moral
transgressions. Guilt and fear of punishment go together. Thus,
the notion that one will suffer great consequences for walking
away from one’s financial obligations not only seems possible, but
feels quite right. It just can’t be that one can walk away from their
mortgage with no significant consequence. As such, people rarely
question apocalyptic descriptions of foreclosure’s consequences.
142
Anaheim Housing Counseling Agency,
http://www.anaheimhousingcounselingagency.org/id21.html (last visited Oct.
10, 2009); see also Fannie Mae, Foreclosure Prevention FAQs,
http://www.fanniemae.com/homeowners/frequently-asked-questions.html (last
visited Oct. 10, 2009) warning:
Foreclosures are extremely damaging to your credit and may
impact your credit rating for as long as seven years. A
foreclosure can make it difficult to get a loan for a future
home purchase, college expenses, or to get a major credit card.
If you are able to get credit, your interest rates will likely be
higher. For most people, it is well worth the time and effort to
avoid foreclosure.
See also, NPR, supra note 124 (quoting Ellen Schloemer, director of
research at the Center for Responsible Lending, for the proposition that “[i]t
takes a decade to recover from a foreclosure.”).
143
See, e.g., Dwight Merunka et. al., Modeling and Measuring the
Impact of Fear, Guilt and Shame Appeals on Persuasion for Health
Communication: a Study of Anti-Alcohol Messages (Working Paper,
2007)(finding that their study showed “that a threatening message implying fear,
guilt and shame together might well be the most persuasive.”), available at:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=963593. See also, Linda Brennan & Wayne Binney,
Fear, Guilt, and Shame Appeals in Social Marketing , J. BUS. RESEARCH (2009);
Lauren G. Block, Self-Referenced Fear and Guilt Appeals: The Moderating
Role of Self-Construal, 35 J. APPLIED SOC. PSYCH. 11 (2005); Francesco
Mancini & Amelia Gangemi, The Role of Responsibility and Fear of Guilt in
Hypothesis-Testing, 37 J. BEHAVIOR THERAPY & EXPERIMENTAL PSYCHIATRY
333 (2006); see also Guilt And Fear Motivate Better Than Hope, SCIENCE
DAILY, http://www.sciencedaily.com/releases/2006/02/060213091147.htm (last
visited Sept. 17, 2009).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
33
default. Moreover, the costs of default are not nearly as extreme as
these same institutions typically misrepresent them to be. In
reality: homeowners face no risk of a deficiency judgment in
many states144 or, regardless of the state, for FHA loans or loans
held by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac;145 even in recourse states,
lenders are unlikely to pursue a deficiency judgment because it is
economically inefficient to do so;146 there is no tax liability on
“forgiven portions” of home mortgages under current federal tax
law in effect until 2012;147 defaulting on one’s mortgage does not
mean that one’s other credit lines will be revoked;148 and most
people can expect to recover from the negative impact of
foreclosure on their credit score within a two years149
Homeowners with high credit scores, however, may have
an especially hard time accepting the notion that a few years of
poor credit is no big deal. The hard to convince include the vast
majority of homeowners with prime loans, 94% of whom had
credit scores above 660 when they purchased their homes.
(and,
meanwhile, two years of poor credit need not seriously impact
one’s life).
150
Most
American homeowners see their good credit scores not only in
utilitarian terms (i.e. – as helpful in increasing one’s purchasing
power) but also as a “source of pride,” or a statement of their good
moral character.151
144
See Andra Ghent and Marianna Kudlyak, Recourse and Residential
Mortgage Default: Theory and Evidence from U.S. States, Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Working Paper No. 09-10, 5 (July 10, 2009), available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1432437 (listing Alaska, Arizona, California, Iowa,
Minnesota, Montana, North Carolina, North Dakota, Washington and Wisconsin
as non-recourse states).
Indeed, the view that one’s credit score
reflects one’s character, or at least one’s sense of personal
responsibility and trustworthiness, is widespread in American
145
Id. at 3 (nothing deficiency judgments are barred for FHA loans)
and .
146
Ralph Roberts, Top Myths About Loan Modification, REALTY TIMES
(Jan. 6, 2009) http://realtytimes.com/rtpages/20090126_myths.htm.
147
Christie, supra note ___ at 2.
148
See Mortgage Forgiveness Debt Relief Act of 2007.
149
Christie, supra note __ at 1-2; Nina Silberstein, How Foreclosure
Affects Your Credit Score, AOL REAL ESTATE,
http://realestate.aol.com/article/credit/_a/how-foreclosure-affects-your-credit-
score/2009041001.(last visited Oct. 10, 2009).
150
ROBERT AVERY ET. AL., CREDIT RISK, CREDIT SCORING, AND THE
PERFORMANCE OF HOME MORTGAGES (1996), available at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/1996/796lead.pdf (noting that
93.6% of conventional fix-rate mortgages have credit scores in the high range,
meaning above 660).
151
Rashmi Dyal-Chand, Human Worth as Collateral, 38 RUTGERS L.J.
793 (2007) (“A good credit score itself is now something about which to be
proud, and a bad credit score is something about which to be ashamed”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
34
culture.152 This belief is not surprising given that the federal
statute that governs credit reporting, the Fair Credit Reporting Act
(“FCRA”), describes credit reporting as a “mechanism for
investigating and evaluating the credit worthiness, credit standing,
credit capacity, character, and general reputation of
consumers.”153
A bad credit score is – by design - meant to reflect not only
one’s poor creditworthiness, but also one’s poor moral character.
For individuals to lose their good credit is thus to lose not only
“their self-conceptions as people who keep their promises and pay
their debts on time,” but part of their “human worth” as well.
154
Even being “perceived as having bad credit” – such as having
one’s credit card turned down at a restaurant – is deeply
humiliating to most Americans.155 A bad credit score is nothing
less than a reputational scarlet letter that, because of the
“omnipresence of the credit reporting system,”156 follows
individuals wherever they go. As a result, Americans engage in a
great deal of “self-regulation in order to maintain good credit
scores.” The lending industry in turn “uses credit scores as a
threat” to constrain borrower behavior.157
This power to threaten borrowers means that though
mortgage agreements in non-recourse states contain an implied put
option, or contractual option to default and transfer ownership of
the home to the lender, the law plays a subordinate role in lender-
borrower relations. A borrower might in fact walk without legal
penalty, but the lender holds the borrower’s human worth as
collateral – and will likely trash it in retaliation for the borrower’s
exercise of their contractual right to default.
158
152
See id. at 793 (noting that “there appears to be a growing trend of
using credit reports as a proxy for screening and decision-making processes
outside the context of credit transactions, and in contexts where character was
once assessed in a more holistic manner. For instance, some relationship experts
now recommend using credit reports to evaluate the trustworthiness and
suitability of a potential romantic partner, while some businesses forego the
interview screening process entirely in favor of the information about an
individual that may be gleaned from a credit report”).
The credit
reporting system thus subordinates the law to social norms, and
makes it impossible for a strategic defaulter to avoid the
153
15 U.S.C. § 1681(a)(2) (2000)(emphasis added).
154
Id.
155
Id.
156
Id.
157
Id.
158
Id. (“In the consumer context, the connection between credit reports,
credit, and social status provides a means of eliminating a person's sense of
honor. Simply put, by reporting negative information to a credit bureau, a lender
can limit a borrower's acquisition of status-enhancing goods and services, and
more basically, lower her social standing”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
35
reputational penalty of default, - even by packing up and moving
across the country. Indeed, for seven years, perfect strangers who
access the defaulter’s credit report will learn of the moral misdeed
and express their disapproval, if only by changing their tone of
voice in the way that individuals tend to do when addressing
someone of a lesser social status.159
In short, although the financial sting of a temporarily poor
credit score may be relatively easy to mitigate,
160
the damage to
one’s reputation and sense of self worth may be both more intense
and more enduring. This reality brings the question back full circle
to whether seriously underwater homeowners may be acting in
utility-maximizing ways by not walking away from their
mortgages. Indeed they may be - if emotional suffering is as a
mere transaction cost of default. But whether the behavior is
utility-maximizing misses the point. The point is that the credit
reporting system operates in conjunction with other economic,
political and social institutions as means of social control by
increasing the emotional cost of default. Moreover, the credit
reporting system operates largely outside legal process as a norm
enforcer,161
VI. The Asymmetry of Homeowner and Lender Norms
ensuring immediate reputational punishment for those
individuals who might be tempted to flout their “moral
commitment to pay” by exercising their legal right to default.
One obvious response to the above discussion is that
society benefits when people honor their financial obligations and
behave according to social and moral norms, rather than strictly
legal or market norms. This may be true if lenders behaved
according to the same social and moral norms. In the case of
lender-borrower behavior, however, there is a clear imbalance in
placing personal responsibility on the borrower to honor their
“promise to pay” in order to relieve the lender of their agreement
159
Seven years is the length of time that the fact of the foreclosure
remains on an individual’s credit report (though its effect on the actual score
will effectively disappear long before then).
160
For example, one might make any purchases for which one will
foreseeably need credit before default and use a debit card in place of a credit
card for purchases and rental car reservations after default.
161
The credit reporting system is governed by the Fair Credit Reporting
Act (“FCRA”) 15 U.S.C. § 1681. The “system” consists of a “consumer report,”
defined by the FCRA as “any written, oral, or other communication of any
information by a consumer reporting agency bearing on a consumer's credit
worthiness, credit standing, credit capacity, character, general reputation,
personal characteristics, or mode of living which is used or expected to be used
or collected in whole or in part for the purpose of serving as a factor in
establishing the consumer's eligibility for credit, insurance, or any other purpose
permitted by the FCRA. 15 U.S.C. § 1681a(d)(1)”
Underwater and Not Walking Away
36
to take back the home in lieu of payment. Given lenders generally
superior knowledge and understanding of both mortgage
instruments and valuation of real estate, it seems only fair to hold
them to the benefit of their bargain. At a basic level, sound
underwriting of mortgage loans requires lenders to ensure that a
loan is sufficiently collateralized in the event of default.162
As discussed above, a textbook premise of economics is
that a home’s value, even an owner occupied one, is “the current
value of the rent payments that could be earned from renting the
property at market prices.”
In
other words, in appraising a home the lender should ensure that the
loan amount, at the least, does not exceed the intrinsic market
value of the home.
163
As such, historical home prices
have hewed nationally to a price-to-annual-rent ratio of roughly
15-to-1.164 At the peak of the market, however, price-to-rent
ratios reached 38-to-1 in the most inflated markets, and the
national average reached 23-to-1.165
Moreover, since lenders generally arrange the appraisal
(which home buyers must pay for) and home buyers rely upon the
lender to ensure the home is worth the purchase price,
If personal responsibility is
the operative value, then lenders who ignored basic economic
principles (of which they should have been aware) should bear at
least equal responsibility to homeowners for issuing collateralized
loans that were far in excess of the intrinsic value of the home.
166
one might
argue that lender should bear much more than 50% responsibility
for the bad investment of the homeowner and lender. As Joseph
Stiglitz has explained, “for the most part, the lenders were, or
should have been, far more financially sophisticated than the
borrowers.”167 Lenders “should [thus] be made to bear the
consequences of their failures to assess risk.”168
162
See e.g., Financial Web, Mortgage Loan Underwriting,
http://www.finweb.com/mortgage-loan-education/mortgage-loan-
underwriting.html (last visited Oct. 10, 2009)
163
JIN RHO, ET. AL., supra note 25, at 3.
164
Id. at 4.
165
Shawn Tully, Real Estate: Buy, Sell, or Hold, FORTUNE, Nov. 7,
2007, available at
http://money.cnn.com/2007/11/06/real_estate/home_prices.fortune/index.htm
166
See James Hagerty, Reappraising Home Appraisers, WALL ST. J.,
Aug. 18, 2009 (noting that, “Appraisals are supposed to shield home buyers
from paying too much and lenders from overestimating the value of collateral. If
appraisals come in too high, buyers may overpay, making defaults more
likely.”).
167
Memorandum from Joseph E. Stiglitz to The Commission of
Experts of the President of the UN General Assembly on Reforms of the
International Monetary and Financial System, 1 , available at http://www.un-
gls.org/docs/ga/cfr/memo_foreclosures.pdf
168
Id.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
37
Indeed, lenders’ mortgage default risk models have long
shown that the loan-to-value ratio is a critical factor in default
risk.169 Lender underwriting practices thus traditionally required
that homeowners have sufficient equity (usually by making a
sufficient down payment) such that default would never be the “in
the money option.”170 Lenders relaxed this requirement, however,
as credit default models showed that few borrowers were
“ruthless,” meaning that few borrowers default as soon as the loan
value exceeds the market value of the home.171 Lenders thus
moved toward models that relied heavily on credit history as the
predictor of default risk. These models showed, for example, that
only 0.9% of borrowers with “high” credit scores and 4% of
borrowers with “medium” credit scores default on their
mortgages.172 This led lenders to conclude that default risk was
sufficiently low for borrowers with high and medium credit scores
that lenders could profitably offer a variety of alternative mortgage
products including zero-down loans, interest-only ARMS, and
negative amortization loans.173
In other words, lenders lost sight of the importance of
positive equity in lowering the risk of mortgage default, and failed
to ensure that homes were actually worth what they were being
purchased for.
174
This is not to say that lenders are solely
responsible for the housing run-up and bust, but that they do in fact
bear a substantial portion of the blame – and thus should thus bear
a substantial portion of the cost.175
169
Vandell, supra at 215 (noting the LTV’s dominant effect on
mortgage default was initially validated in the 1970 Herzog and Earley study).
One might argue, in fact, that
170
Id. at 212-213, 218.
171
Id. at 224 (finding that the first option-based models overestimated
the ruthless default of homeowners in comparison to that which was actually
observable in the market).
172
See AVERY ET. AL., supra note 145.
173
See Kerry D. Vandell, Handing Over the Keys, A Perspective on
Mortgage Default Research, 21 J. AM. REAL ESTATE & URBAN ECON. ASS’N
211 (1993)
174
See, e.g., CNBC.com, Boom, Bust and Blame - The Inside Story of
America's Economic Crisis, http://www.cnbc.com/id/32756455/ (last visited
Oct. 10, 2009) (noting that “[f]inancial institutions big and small got caught up
in the lending frenzy. Some were fly-by-night operations that made millions
through questionable loans. Others were well-known firms with strong
reputations, blinded by the promise of huge mortgage profits.”).
175
Of course, others share in the blame as well, including mortgage
brokers and appraisers who conspired to inflate home values, see e.g., LARRY
NEUMEISTER, 41 people in 4 states charged in mortgage fraud, Associated
Press Wire, October 15, 2009 (on file with author), and buyer’s real estate
agents, who pushed buyers to buy at inflated prices and failed to warn of an
impending bust that they knew, or should have known, was coming – or at the
very least failed to inform buyers once monthly trends began to show declining
prices. See Lew Sichelman, Legal battles over real estate transactions increase,
LOS ANGELES TIMES, October 4, 2009.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
38
the value of personal responsibility would require lenders to own
up to their share of the blame, and work with underwater
homeowners by voluntarily writing off some of the negative
equity.
But lenders, of course, do not operate according norms of
personal responsibility, and seek instead to maximize profit (or
minimize losses). Indeed, to the extent that the lender is a
corporation, the directors and executives of the corporation have a
legal duty to shareholders to maximize profit and/or minimize
losses. Appealing to this duty, it has been suggested that, given
the great cost to lenders of foreclosure, they have an economic
incentive to modify loans for homeowners in danger of default.176
This argument has flown in the face of the reality, however, that
lenders have been reluctant to modify loans, even for borrowers in
the pre-foreclosure process.177
Recent studies seeking to explain this apparently irrational
behavior have shown that lenders are simply operating to
maximize profit and minimize losses, just as they would be
expected to do.
178
First, lenders know that borrowers with high
credit scores are unlikely to default even at high levels of negative
equity.179 To modify loans for these homeowners would be to
throw money away – and to encourage more homeowners to ask
for modifications. Second, a significant number of homeowners
who temporarily default on their mortgages “self-cure” without
any help from their lender – though self cure rates have dropped
precipitously in the last two years.180
176
MORTGAGE BANKER’S ASSOCIATION, LENDER’S COST OF
FORECLOSURE, (2008), available at
http://www.nga.org/Files/pdf/0805FORECLOSUREMORTGAGE.PDF
(explaining that foreclosure is a prohibitively costly exercise for the mortgage
industry as it involves significant lost payments on principal, interest, as well as
necessitating legal, administrative, and property maintenance fees, all of which
are incurred by the lender).
Again, to modify the loans of
177
Manuel Adelino, Kristopher Gerardi, & Paul Willen, Why Don’t
Lenders Renegotiate More Home Mortgages? Redefaults, Self-Cures, and
Securitization (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Working Paper 2009-17, Aug.
2009), available at http://www.frbatlanta.org/invoke.cfm?objectid=149C4D27-
5056-9F12-12C089648203E1FD&method=display.
178
Id. See also Foote, et. al., supra note 14 at 1 (explain that “While
investors might be foreclosing when it would be socially efficient to modify,
there is little evidence to suggest they are acting against their own interests when
they do so.”)(emphasis in original)
179
Manuel Adelino, Kristopher Gerardi, & Paul Willen, Why Don’t
Lenders Renegotiate More Home Mortgages? Redefaults, Self-Cures, and
Securitization (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Working Paper 2009-17, Aug.
2009), available at http://www.frbatlanta.org/invoke.cfm?objectid=149C4D27-
5056-9F12-12C089648203E1FD&method=display
180
See Foote, et. al., supra note 14 at 2 (noting, “Investors also lose
money when they modify mortgages for borrowers who would have repaid
Underwater and Not Walking Away
39
individuals who would otherwise self cure would be to throw away
money. Third, homeowners with poor credit, or who end up in
arrears because of “triggering events” such as unemployment,
divorce, or other financially devastating circumstances are likely to
default on the modified loan as well.181
Given these economic incentives for the lender, a seriously
underwater homeowner with good credit and solid mortgage
payment history who responsibly calls his lender to work out a
loan modification is likely to be told by his lender that it will not
discuss a loan modification until the homeowner is 30 days or
more delinquent on his mortgage payment.
To modify loans for these
individuals is to waste time and risk housing prices falling further
before the lender eventually has to foreclosure and sell the property
anyway.
182
The lender is
making a bet (and a good one) that the homeowner values his
credit score too much to miss a payment and will just give up the
idea of a loan modification. However, if the homeowner does
what the lender suggests, misses a payment, and calls back to
discuss a loan modification in 30 days, the homeowner is likely to
be told to call back when he is 90 days delinquent.183 In the
meantime, the lender will send the borrower a series of strongly-
worded notices reminding him of his moral obligation to pay and
threatening legal action, including foreclosure and a deficiency
judgment, if the homeowner does not bring his mortgage payments
current. The lender is again making a bet (and again a good one)
that the homeowner will be shamed or frightened into paying their
mortgage. If the homeowner calls the lender’s bluff and calls back
when he is 90 days delinquent, there is a good possibility that he
will be told that his credit score is now so low that he does not
qualify for a loan modification.184
anyway, especially if modifications are done en masse, as proponents insist they
should be.”)
The homeowner must then
decide whether to bring the loan current or face foreclosure. If the
homeowner somehow makes clear to the lender that he has chosen
181
See Id. (“Moreover, the calculation [that lenders are acting against
their own interest] ignores the possibility that borrowers with modified loans
will default again later, usually for the same reason they defaulted in the first
place.”); See also Manuel Adelino, Kristopher Gerardi, & Paul Willen, Why
Don’t Lenders Renegotiate More Home Mortgages? Redefaults, Self-Cures, and
Securitization (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Working Paper 2009-17, Aug.
2009)
182
See Edmund L. Andrews, My Personal Credit Crisis, N.Y. TIMES,
May 14, 2009, available at
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/05/17/magazine/17foreclosure-
t.html?pagewanted=all (describing the author’s efforts to renegotiate his
mortgage with his lender)
183
Id.
184
Id.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
40
foreclosure, the lender may finally be willing to negotiate a loan
modification, a short-sale or a deed-in-lieu of foreclosure – all of
which still leave the homeowner’s credit in tatters (at least
temporary).
Most lenders will, in other words, take full advantage of the
asymmetry of norms between lender and homeowner and will use
the threat of damaging the borrower’s credit score to bring the
homeowner into compliance. Additionally, many lenders will only
bargain when the threat of damaging the homeowner’s credit has
lost its force and it becomes clear to the lender that foreclosure is
imminent absent some accommodation. On a fundamental level,
the asymmetry of moral norms for borrowers and market norms for
lenders gives lenders an unfair advantage in negotiations related to
the enforcement of contractual rights and obligations, including the
borrower’s right to exercise the put option. This imbalance is
exaggerated by the credit reporting system, which gives lenders the
power to threaten borrowers’ human worth and social status by
damaging their credit scores – scores that serve as much as grades
for moral character as they do for creditworthiness.185
VII. Leveling the Playing Field
The result
is a predictable imbalance in which individual homeowners have
born a huge and disproportionate burden of the housing collapse.
While the federal government has given billions to bailout
financial institutions, the primary assistance that it has offered to
underwater homeowners has been allowing them to refinance up to
125% of their home’s current value at “today’s lower interest
rates”186 – if they are current on their mortgage and their original
loan was insured by Freddie Mac or Fannie Mae.187 Additionally,
for homeowners “at risk of imminent default,” the Treasury
Department has encouraged lenders to voluntarily modify loans so
that borrower payments do not exceed 31% of their total monthly
income.188 In order to incentivize such loan modifications, the
Treasury Department has offered lenders $1,000 for each eligible
mortgage they modify, plus $1,000 per year for three years as long
as the borrower remains in the program.189
185
See Rashmi Dyal-Chand, Human Worth as Collateral, 38 RUTGERS
L.J. 793 (2007)
Additionally, once the
186
Press Release, HUD, Sec’y Donovan Announces Expanded
Eligibility For Making Home Affordable Refinancing (Jul.y1, 2009), available
at http://www.hud.gov/news/release.cfm?content=pr09-104.cfm.
187
Id.
188
See Press Release, Dep’t Treasury, Making Home Affordable:
Updated Detailed Program Description (Mar. 4, 2009) available at
http://www.treas.gov/press/releases/reports/housing_fact_sheet.pdf.
189
See id.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
41
lender has absorbed the cost of reducing the monthly debt-to-
income ratio to 38%, the Treasury Department will share the cost,
dollar-for-dollar, of reducing the ratio further to 31%.190
Government policy makers have premised this approach on
two central tenants: (1) that the key to preventing foreclosures is to
ensure that mortgage payments are affordable; and (2) that the
severity of the foreclosure crisis in the United States is due in large
part to lenders unwillingness to renegotiate mortgages to make
them more affordable.
191
Policy makers have grounded this single-
minded focus on affordability upon studies from earlier, less
severe, housing busts that showed that borrowers with affordable
mortgages rarely default.192
There are several problems, however, with focusing on
affordability alone as the key to averting the worsening of the
foreclosure crisis. First, government programs have defined
“unaffordable” as a total monthly payment exceeding 30% of one’s
gross monthly income.
193
This arbitrary cut off does not account
for the reality that even if one’s payment doesn’t exceed 30% of
gross monthly income, paying - for example - $3000 a month for a
home that could be purchased or rented today for around $1000 a
month is financially unwise. Or as “an economist might argue ...
an unaffordable mortgage is one that is really too expensive, in the
sense that the benefits that come with making payments on the
mortgage no longer outweigh the opportunity costs of doing so.”194
Conversely, paying 30% of gross monthly income to a
mortgage will leave many middle-to-low-income individuals with
little to spare – especially to the extent that individuals have other
significant financial obligations such as child care or medical bills.
Indeed, leaving aside monthly budget concerns, 30% (or even
20%) of one’s income is a significant percentage if the payment is
essentially being thrown away into a large negative equity hole out
To account for this fact, “affordable” might instead be defined not
only according to one’s grossly income, but also in relation to the
fair rental value of one’s home. A home that cost three times more
to own than it would to rent is by definition unaffordable. On the
other hand, a home that cost less to own than it would to rent might
be not too expensive even if the payment exceeds 30% of one’s
gross monthly income, as long as one could make the payment
with room to spare.
190
Id.
191
Adelino, Gerardi, & Willen, supra note 165.
192
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 21
193
See HUD, Affordable Housing,
http://www.hud.gov/offices/cpd/affordablehousing/index.cfm (last visited Oct.
6, 2009) (stating, “The generally accepted definition of affordability is for a
household to pay no more than 30 percent of its annual income on housing.”).
194
See Foote, et. al, supra note 70 at 4.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
42
from which one is not likely to dig. Once a home has become an
albatross instead of an investment, struggling to pay a mortgage
makes no financial sense, almost regardless of one’s monthly
payment. For many homeowners, technical affordability is not the
lone consideration. Relative affordability and negative equity both
matter as well – and once negative equity is severe enough, it may
overwhelm other considerations.
Recognizing this reality, number of proposals have been
put forth to address the relative affordability and/or negative equity
problem. Joseph Stiglitz has suggested, for example, that the
government should itself become a lender and issue mortgages at
low interest rates, which would help address the relative
affordability issue and partially compensate for negative equity.195
Others have suggested that the government use stimulus funds to
buy down underwater mortgages196 or assist homeowners through
grants that would cover a portion of their payments.197
In contrast to a government bailout of underwater
homeowners, others have proposed measures that would force
lenders to write off some of the principal of underwater mortgages,
Each of
these proposals would bring some balance to the government’s
current approach to the mortgage crisis by providing direct
assistance to homeowners as opposed to injecting money into the
banking system in hopes that some of the benefit will trickle down
in the form of greater credit availability. Equally as important,
they would circumvent the problems created by norm asymmetry
between borrowers and lenders because borrowers could go to the
government for help regardless of their lender’s willingness to
renegotiate.
195
Stiglitz has argued that such a program would allow the government
to earn a return on these mortgages and incentivize the mortgage industry to
compete by restructuring loan terms. Memorandum from Joseph E. Stiglitz to
The Commission of Experts of the President of the UN General Assembly on
Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System, 2-3 , available at
http://www.un-gls.org/docs/ga/cfr/memo_foreclosures.pdf. However, in order
to adequately compensate for negative equity, especially for homeowners who
are hundreds of thousands of dollars underwater, interest rates would have to be
truly low - as in somewhere around 2-3%.
196
Rebel A. Cole, The Housing-Asset Relief Program: A Plan for
Stabilizing the Housing and Securities Markets (April 22, 2009). Available at
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1338883 (proposing that “$300 billion in TARP
or stimulus funds” be “used to write down the principals on underwater
mortgages.”)
197
Christopher L. Foote, et., al., A Proposal to Help Distressed
Homeowners: A Government Payment-Sharing Plan, FRB of Boston Public
Policy Brief No. 09-1 (July 9, 2009), available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1432514 (proposing a “government payment-sharing
arrangement” whereby the government would pay part of the homeowner's
existing mortgage, providing a “significant reduction in the homeowner's
monthly mortgage payment.”)
Underwater and Not Walking Away
43
without the government picking up the tab. For example, Adam
Levitin has proposed allowing bankruptcy judges to write down
mortgages on primary residences, which is prohibited under
current bankruptcy law.198
Partially in response to this concern, Eric Posner and Luigi
Zingales have suggested changing federal bankruptcy law to allow
“prepackaged,” or streamlined, mortgage cram-downs under
Chapter 13 of the Bankruptcy Code.
This proposal too is a step in the right
direction in that it would help compensate for the problems of
norm asymmetry by eliminating the need for borrowers to
negotiate with lenders. However, Levitin’s proposal would help
only underwater homeowners who qualified for bankruptcy and
could show that they could not “afford” their mortgage payments.
It would thus fail to assist many responsible underwater
homeowners who did not reach beyond their means, but simply
purchased at the wrong time.
199
Under Posner and
Zingales’ intriguing proposal, any homeowner who lives in a ZIP
code where the median home price has dropped by more than 20
percent from its peak would have the right to submit a “Chapter 13
prepack.”200 This prepack “would simply contain a new mortgage
amount that is equal to the old mortgage amount discounted by the
percentage decline of the median house price for the ZIP code.
Monthly payments would decline by the same percentage; the term
of the mortgage would not be changed.”201 The creditor would
not have the right to oppose the prepack, but would be entitled to a
percentage of the home’s appreciate upon sale equal to the
percentage reduction in the principal pursuant to the prepack.202
Like the Levitin proposal, the prepackage bankruptcy
would be a positive step in circumventing the barriers to
renegotiation caused by norm asymmetry. The prepack also has
several advantages to the Levitin proposal, including that it would
impose less of a burden on the courts because the prepackage
bankruptcy would be “automated, requiring only a rubber stamp by
a bankruptcy judge.”
203
198
See Adam Levitin, Resolving the Foreclosure Crisis: Modification
of Mortgages in Bankruptcy, (April 24, 2009) Available at SSRN:
Nevertheless, the prepack proposal has
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1071931 (arguing for modification of home-mortgage
debt in bankruptcy proceedings); See also Eric A. Posner & Luigi Zingales ,
The Housing Crisis and Bankruptcy Reform: The Prepackaged Chapter 13
Approach 21 (School of Business Research Paper No. 09-11; U of Chicago Law
& Economics, Olin Working Paper No. 459, February 25, 2009), available at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1349364. (discussing similar proposal from Senator
Durbin).
199
Posner & Zingales, supra note , at .
200
Id.
201
Id.
202
Id.
203
Id.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
44
significant drawbacks as well, including that it would intrude ex
post into the contractual relationship of private parties and would
create additional administrative burdens for already over-burdened
bankruptcy courts.204 It is also a blunt instrument in that it
arbitrarily limits cramdowns to ZIP codes where prices have
declined 20% and does not account for the often great variation of
depreciation within a single ZIP code.205
While the Posner and Zingales’ and the Levitin proposals
are worth considering, understanding norm asymmetry suggests
other possibilities. One solution that naturally follows, for
example, would be for the government – or some consumer
advocacy group - to begin a public education campaign
encouraging underwater homeowners to walk if their lender is
unwilling to negotiate. Whether or not such an approach would be
effective, it would likely be so distasteful to most policy makers,
and many readers of this article, that this idea will not be pursued
further here.
At a minimum, however, federally-approved and supported
housing and credit counseling agencies should cease in sending the
fear-laden message that foreclosure should be avoided at all cost.
They should also provide accurate information – including that
defaulting homeowners face no risk of a deficiency judgment in
many states206 or, regardless of the state, for FHA loans or loans
held by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac;207 there is currently no tax
liability on “forgiven portions” of home mortgages;208 and most
people can expect to recover from the negative impact of
foreclosure on their credit score within a two years.209
204
Id.
In other
words, the government should, at least, stop perpetuating scary
myths about the consequences of foreclosure and could tone down
its moral rhetoric.
205
The plan would thus be over-inclusive and under-inclusive, allowing
some owners a write-down even when their particular neighborhood had not
experienced declines exceeding the magical 20% cut off, but denying relief to
others who neighborhoods had experienced steep declines, but whose overall
ZIP code had fared better than a 20% decline.
206
See Andra Ghent and Marianna Kudlyak, Recourse and Residential
Mortgage Default: Theory and Evidence from U.S. States, Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Working Paper No. 09-10, 5 (July 10, 2009), available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1432437 (listing Alaska, Arizona, California, Iowa,
Minnesota, Montana, North Carolina, North Dakota, Washington and Wisconsin
as non-recourse states).
207
Id. at 3 (nothing deficiency judgments are barred for FHA loans)
and .
208
Christie, supra note ___ at 2.
209
Christie, supra note __ at 1-2; Nina Silberstein, How Foreclosure
Affects Your Credit Score, AOL REAL ESTATE,
http://realestate.aol.com/article/credit/_a/how-foreclosure-affects-your-credit-
score/2009041001.(last visited Oct. 10, 2009).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
45
Given the credit rating system’s role in enforcing norm
asymmetry, however, additional measures might be necessary to
level the playing field between borrowers and lenders and
empower homeowners to renegotiate underwater mortgages. One
such solution, for example, would be to amend the Fair Credit
Reporting Act to prevent lenders from reporting mortgage defaults
and foreclosures to credit rating agencies.210
The suggestion that Congress should amend the Fair Credit
Reporting Act to prevent lenders from reporting mortgage defaults
is premised upon the underlying mortgage contract, in which
lenders agree to hold the house alone as collateral. In the case of
underwater mortgages, however, the portion of the mortgage above
the home’s present value essentially becomes unsecured. Lenders
compensate for this by holding the borrowers’ credit score, and
thus their human worth, as collateral – thereby altering the
underlining agreement that the home serves as the sole collateral.
As a consequence, lenders are often able to reap the benefit, but
escape the costs, of their bargain.
To be clear, however,
this proposal is not presented here as the only possible solution to
the exclusion of all others. Rather it is presented as a jumping off
point for further discussion as to how norm asymmetry can be
addressed and lenders encouraged to voluntary renegotiate
mortgages. At the very least, it is a useful thought experiment. At
the best, it may in fact be the key to eliminating norm asymmetry
between lenders and borrowers, forcing a more equitable division
of the housing crisis’s financial burden, and preventing the
foreclosure crisis from spreading to prime loans.
Preventing lenders from reporting mortgage defaults to
credit rating agencies would, as a practical matter, eliminate
lenders’ ability to hold borrowers’ human worth as collateral.
Such a change would also serve as an important signal from the
government – sending the message that a borrower who exercises a
contractual right to default should not be viewed as immoral or
irresponsible. It would thus help considerably in leveling the
playing field between lenders and borrowers. With the threat of
damage to the borrower’s credit score removed, the borrower could
more credibly threaten to walk absent a principal reduction. It
bears emphasizing, however, that the borrower would be unlikely
to bargain “ruthlessly” because, even without the credit reputation
210
Ideally, this change would be coupled with an extension beyond
2012 of the federal tax waiver on “forgiven” portions of one’s mortgage and a
national anti-deficiency statute barring lenders from pursuing homeowners for a
mortgage’s unsatisfied portion upon foreclosure. Though not without
controversy, extending the tax waiver and passing an anti-deficiency statute
address the underlying economic costs of default to the borrower and, other
consequences aside, it should therefore be self-explanatory why they would help
improve borrowers bargaining position.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
46
hit, there are significant transaction costs to moving and finding a
new home.211 Indeed, because of these costs, and attachment to
home,212 few homeowners would walk at less than 10% negative
equity.213
Thus, if a mortgage were underwater, for example, by 20%,
the lender and homeowner might agree to share equally in
absorbing the loss - or a homeowner might agree to absorb all of
the negative equity in exchange for a reduction in the interest rate.
The parties might also agree to condition any reduction in principal
on the lender sharing in future appreciation – in effect converting
the mortgage into a shared equity loan. In other words, the lender
and homeowner would be free to negotiate a mutually beneficial
arrangement to continue the mortgagor-mortgagee relationship, or
they could settle for the benefit of their original bargain and the
mortgagor could have the house.
Additionally, this approach would have significant
advantages over Posner and Zingales’ proposal for forced
cramdowns. First, it would allow the parties to come to their own
mutually agreeable solution to the negative equity problem,
without the government intruding into a private contractual
relationship and rewriting the contract itself. Second, it allows for
nuanced, borrower-specific solutions, rather across the board
treatment for whole ZIP codes, or arbitrary cut-offs based upon a
set percentage of the borrower’s gross monthly income. Third, it
would not require the government to create a new bureaucratic
structure or expend any taxpayer money - nor would it impose new
regulations on lenders. The proposal simply identifies a distortion
in the market created by norm asymmetry and eliminates that
distortion. Indeed, the proposal to eliminate the credit threat is, at
heart, a market-based solution. It should thus be preferable to a
government bailout of homeowners or a government take-over of
the lending industry.214
211
See ROBERT AVERY ET. AL., supra note 145.
By the same token, it should be attractive
212
Indeed, lenders benefit not only from negative emotions such as
guilt and fear, but also positive attachment to the idea of homeownership. This
emotional attachment to homeownership is also socially cultivated and been
internalized by most Americans, who generally see homeownership as both a
good investment and an integral part of the American dream -and thus may cling
to their homes when they could walk away, rent something nicer, and put the
money they save into an investment with better returns.
213
Guiso et al., supra note 11, at 21.
214
The proposal is, of course, not likely to satisfy those that believe
homeowners have a moral obligation to pay their mortgage regardless of
whether it would be more efficient to breach. Nor, it goes without saying, is the
proposal going to be welcomed by the lending industry.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
47
to consumer advocates in that it protects the credit of underwater
homeowners and gives them more leverage to negotiate. 215
Nevertheless, some might still object that eliminating the
credit threat would encourage default among underwater
homeowners.
216
215
There is already a large and growing industry devoted to helping
underwater homeowners negotiate write-downs with lenders. As evidence of
the size of this industry, there have been “massive numbers of complaints” in
California against lawyers who have taken fees to renegotiate mortgages and
have failed to deliver. Jim Wasserman, Loan modification firms banned from
demanding upfront fees, SACRAMENTO BEE, 6B, Oct. 13, 2009. As a result,
lawmakers in California passed legislation to bar up-front fees for mortgage
renegotiation services. See Advanced Fees For Loan Modification are now
Illegal in California, California Department of Real Estate. Available at
http://www.dre.ca.gov/pdf_docs/FraudWarningsCaDRE03_2009.pdf It thus
seems fair to say that eliminating the credit threat would – at a minimum - help
the thousands of people who are already trying to negotiate with their lenders,
but find they have little leverage unless they are willing signal their willingness
to walk by missing payments and sacrificing their credit scores.
But that is, in part, the point: in an environment
216
Rather than objecting that eliminating the credit threat would
encourage default among underwater homeowners, others are likely to argue the
opposite: namely, that eliminating the credit threat would do nothing to alter
homeowner behavior. This objection would be grounded upon surveys that have
shown that many people don’t understand what a credit score is, much less care
about their own. See, Oren Bar-Gill and Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit
Safer, 157 U. PA. L. REV. 1 (2008)(arguing that “survey evidence also suggests
that “[m]ost consumers do not understand what credit scores measure, what
good and bad scores are, and how scores can be improved.”) However, credit
knowledge surveys have not isolated people with high credit scores to see what
they know or how they feel about credit scores (and, as discussed above, 94% of
people with prime loans have high credit scores). This subset of the population
with high credit scores likely cares more and know more about credit scores
than the general population. Moreover, despite headlines to the contrary, credit
knowledge surveys have actually shown that a very significant portion of the
population does in fact understand the importance of good credit, care about
their credit scores, and understand the basics of credit reporting. See e.g., Press
Release, Consumer Fed'n of Am. & Providian, Most Consumers Do Not
Understand Credit Scores According to a New Comprehensive Survey 1 (2004),
available at http://www.consumerfed.org/pdfs/092104creditscores.pdf
(concluding that “most consumers don’t understand credit scores” despite
finding that “most customers correctly understand that lenders use credit
scores,” 34% correctly understand that credit scores measure credit risk, 35%
understand that credit scores are unrelated to income, and 60% correctly
understand how to improve their credit score); Poll: Consumers Don't
Understand Credit Reporting, Favor Reforms, Ins. J., Aug. 11, 2003,
http://www.insurancejournal.com/news/national/2003/08/11/31410.htm (finding
that consumers don’t understand many specifics of credit reporting, but finding
that 97% understand that they have the right to see their credit report, 81% know
that consumers who fail to qualify for a loan have the right to a free credit
report, 46% understand that in most states they must pay a fee to obtain their
credit report, 45% understand that their credit score may be lowered if they use
all of the credit available on their credit card, and that 73% understand that their
credit score measures their credit-worthiness.); Survey: 27% of Consumers Do
Not Read Credit Reports, Credit & Collections World, Oct. 5, 2006,
Underwater and Not Walking Away
48
where there was less stigma attached to default and where
homeowners could more credibly threaten to walk away, lenders
would be more willing to negotiate with underwater homeowners.
The end result would paradoxically be fewer defaults - as
homeowners would not feel compelled – or be told – to default
before the lender would negotiate. Moreover, even if there were
more initial defaults, fewer of these defaults would end in
foreclosures - as a missed payment would signal the homeowner’s
seriousness to the lender and bring the lender more quickly to the
table. This would stand in sharp contrast to the current
environment where lenders often have an economic incentive not
to work with borrowers, on the theory that the vast majority of
those who threaten to default will not follow through and that
modifying mortgages of underwater homeowners will simply
encourage more defaults.217
The proposal’s value in forcing lenders to negotiate should
not be underestimated. Indeed, “every major policy action to date
has involved encouraging lenders, in one way or another, to
renegotiate loan terms in order to reduce borrower debt loads.”
This includes, of course, the Making Home Affordable program,
which tries to encourage renegotiation by offering modest financial
incentives to lenders. As the paucity of loan modifications under
http://creditandcollectionsworld.com/article.html?id=20061016NIJPR6OI
(finding that 73% of individuals have at some point checked their credit score);
Scores & Jobs, CardFlash, Sept. 14, 2007, http://
www.cardweb.com/cardflash/2007/09/14/scores-jobs (finding hat 60% of
individuals had checked their credit score and that a full 22% of respondents
check their credit score every year); U.S. Gov't Accountability Office, Credit
Reporting Literacy: Consumers Understood the Basics but Could Benefit from
Targeted Educational Efforts 10-11 (2005), available at http://
www.gao.gov/new.items/d05223.pdf (reporting that 70% of respondents
correctly defined a credit score). Individuals who care about and understand
their credit score likely constitute a much more significant portion of people
with prime loans (with is only subset of individuals about which this proposal is
concerned) than the general population. Moreover, one does not really need to
understand much about one’s credit score to not want to mess it up – and even
the most ignorant homeowner likely knows a foreclosure will hurt his credit. It
thus makes sense that removing the credit threat would alter the behavior of at
least a significant minority of underwater homeowners.
217
Even a relatively modest increase in the number of credible threats
of default could alter the economic calculation for lenders that causes them not
to renegotiate. Such would be the likely outcome of removing the credit threat -
as the signaling function of a late payment would be less costly to borrowers,
meaning many more people would default if necessary in order to bring lenders
to the table. But, it should be emphasized that the increase in defaults would
likely be temporary - as lenders would soon comprehend that it would be less
costly to negotiate with borrowers who threaten default before they actually stop
making payment.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
49
this program attests,218 however, offering lenders a few thousand
dollars to modify delinquent loans does not alter the underlying
economic incentives or the lender-borrower dynamic that drives
lenders to prefer foreclosure to renegotiation.219 Voluntary
renegotiation of home mortgages has remained the elusive “public
policy holy grail.”220
Despite these benefits, one might still object to the proposal
on the theory that the lender’s ability to collateralize borrowers’
credit scores reduces risk to the lender, thereby allowing them to
offer lower interest rates.
This failure to effectively encourage
voluntary renegotiation has stemmed – at least in part - from policy
makers’ failure to appreciate the role of norm asymmetry in
lenders’ unwillingness to negotiate with borrowers (at least not
until borrowers have shown their willingness to sacrifice their
credit scores). Eliminating the credit threat may thus, in fact, be
part of the key to unlocking the holy grail of voluntary
renegotiation.
221
Thus, the argument would go,
eliminating the credit threat would increase borrowers’ lending
costs and restrict credit. At the outset, it bears noting that this is
the typical argument against most consumer protections – and that
similar arguments can be expected against any proposal that would
effectively shift some of the burden of underwater mortgages off
homeowners and onto lenders.222
218
Though the Treasury Department predicted that these programs
would offer assistance to 7 to 9 million homeowners, only 360,165 loan
modifications had taken place under the program as of August 31, 2009.
Financial Stability, Making Home Affordable Program: Servicer Performance
Report through August 2009, http://www.financialstability.gov/docs/MHA-
Public_090909.pdf (last visited Oct. 10, 2009).
Indeed, the same arguments
about increased interest rates and restricted credit have been made
219
Id. (noting, “No matter which definition of renegotiation we use,
one message is quite clear: lenders rarely renegotiate. Fewer than 3 percent of
the seriously delinquent borrowers in our sample received a concessionary
modification in the year following the first serious delinquency.”)
220
Manuel Adelino, Kristopher Gerardi, & Paul Willen, supra note 165
(noting “there is a consensus among many observers that concessionary
modifications are the most, or possibly the only, effective way of preventing
foreclosures.”)
221
Relatedly, others might argue that barring the reporting of mortgage
defaults would reduce the utility of the credit reporting system in providing
information about the reliability of potential borrowers. This is true only if one
assumes that the same information about borrowers is relevant for secured
verses unsecured debt. However, it would seem that secured debt, such as home
mortgages, should operate in a different sphere than unsecured debt – where in
fact the only collateral the lender has is the borrowers’ credit score. See Avery,
supra note [x] (discussing separate risk assessment model that already exists for
home mortgages)
222
See Posner & Zingales, supra note [x], at [x]. (noting that “[t]he
financial industry opposes any loan modification because it will increase the
future cost of credit and reduce its availability.”).
Underwater and Not Walking Away
50
in opposing mortgage cramdowns – though recent empirical work
by Adam Levitin and Joshua Goodman has suggested that
permitting bankruptcy modification of mortgages would have little
to no impact on mortgage markets. 223
Moreover, any possible costs of eliminating the credit
threat should be weighed against the potentially enormous benefit
of empowering homeowners to more successfully negotiate away
their negative equity. First, numerous studies have shown that
negative home equity reduces consumer spending: the higher the
incidence of negative equity in the housing market, the weaker
aggregate demand in the overall economy.
Predictions of high interest
rates and restricted credit should thus be approached with a healthy
bit of skepticism.
224
Second, negative
home equity is associated with drastically reduced household
mobility,225
223
Adam Levitin and Joshua Goodman, The Effect of Bankruptcy Strip-
Down on Mortgage Markets, Georgetown Law and Economics Research Paper
No. 1087816 (February 6, 2008), available at SSRN:
which has a range of negative macroeconomic effects,
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1087816 (arguing that current and historical data
suggests that permitting bankruptcy modification of mortgages would have no or
little impact on mortgage markets, including mortgage interest rates); and Adam
Levitin, Resolving the Foreclosure Crisis: Modification of Mortgages in
Bankruptcy, (April 24, 2009) Available at
SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1071931 (arguing that “permitting modification
would have little or no impact on mortgage credit cost or availability.”); See
also Adam Levitin,, A Critique of the American Bankers Association's Study on
Credit Card Regulation, Georgetown Law and Economics Research Paper No.
1029191; Georgetown Public Law Research Paper No. 1029191 (August 18,
2008) Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1029191 (disputing
contention by American Bankers Association that credit card regulation
increases interest rates).
224
See Tomas Hellebrandt, et. al., The Economics and Estimation of
Negative Equity, BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY BULLETIN 2009 Q2 (June 12,
2009)(arguing that “A rising incidence of negative equity is often associated
with weak aggregate demand.”); M. Corder and N. Roberts (2008),
‘Understanding dwellings investment’, 48 BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY
BULLETIN 393 (indicating that negative equity reduces the incentive for
homebuilders and homeowners to invest in housing) A. Benito, et. al., House
prices and durables spending, BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY BULLETIN 142–
54 (Summer 2006)(showing that negative equity negatively affects aggregate
consumer spending); Benito, A and Mumtaz, H (2006), Consumption excess
sensitivity, liquidity constraints and the collateral role of housing, Bank of
England Working Paper No. 306. (2008) (negative equity raises the probability
of a household being credit constrained and thus unable to purchase); R. Disney,
et. al., House price shocks, negative equity and household consumption in the
United Kingdom, JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION
(forthcoming 2008)(negative equity leads to greater savings and lower
spending.); and Drowning in Debt, supra note 6 at 16 (noting that negative
equity suppresses middle class consumption)
225
See Tomas Hellebrandt, et. al., The Economics and Estimation of
Negative Equity, BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY BULLETIN 2009 Q2 (June 12,
2009) (indicating that “Negative equity can affect household mobility by
Underwater and Not Walking Away
51
including increased structural unemployment, reduced
productivity, and limited the supply capacity.226
Moreover, barring the reporting of mortgage defaults could
have positive effects on future lender behavior. This is because in
the case of a home mortgage, the lender has the ability to ensure
that the collateral is sufficient to create the proper economic
incentives for borrowers not to default. In other words, they need
not rely upon credit scores to control their risk, but can instead
ensure that the purchase price of the financed home in is line with
historically sustainable price-to-rent ratios, demand sufficient
down payment and eschew interest-only and negative amortization
loans.
Empowering
homeowners to reduce their negative equity through renegotiation
could thus have enormous economic benefit in its own right.
227
The above proposal should not, however, obscure the
broader point: norm asymmetry between borrowers and lenders
creates disincentives for lenders to renegotiate underwater
mortgages and makes it unlikely that lenders will work with
borrowers to address the negative equity issue. Any proposal to
address the problems created by negative equity must account for
this reality – either by addressing the resulting distributional
Lenders would be more inclined to take these sensible
precautions if borrowers were empowered to behave according to
the same market norms as lenders and breach when it is efficient to
do so. This added caution by lenders might in turn help avoid a
repeat of the current housing crisis.
discouraging or restricting households from moving house); A Tversky and D.
Kahneman, Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference-dependent model, 106
THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1039 (1991), (indicating that
individuals are reluctant to move because they do not wish to take a loss on their
home); and A. Henley, Residential mobility, housing equity and the labour
market, 108 ECONOMIC JOURNAL 414 (1998), (finding that twice as many
individuals many would have moved in the early 1990’s in England had they not
been in negative equity); and Fernando V. Ferreira, et. al., Housing Busts and
Household Mobility NBER Working Paper Series (September 2008), available
at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1264572 (discussing the correlation between
decreased household mobility and negative equity). See also Louis Uchitelle,
Unsold Homes Tie Down Would-Be Transplants, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 3, 2008
(noting, “The rapid decline in housing prices is distorting the normal workings
of the American labor market. Mobility opens up job opportunities, allowing
workers to go where they are most needed.” Also noting that labor mobility that
has been seriously hindered by the housing crisis).
226
See A. Henley, Residential mobility, housing equity and the labour
market, 108 ECONOMIC JOURNAL 414 (1998) and Tomas Hellebrandt, et. al., The
Economics and Estimation of Negative Equity, BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY
BULLETIN 2009 Q2 (June 12, 2009).
227
Moreover, to the extent that a mortgage default is relevant to a credit
application, lenders could ask and borrowers could be required to disclose that
information – as borrowers are now required to do even when the default is no
longer reflected in their credit score.
Underwater and Not Walking Away
52
inequities or changing the rules of the game. Viable approaches
could include: (1) cutting lenders out of the picture altogether
through government financing of mortgages at low interest rates;
(2) using stimulus funds to buy down the mortgages of underwater
homeowners;228 (3) forcing lenders to reduce mortgage balances
by court order; or (4) leveling the playing field by eliminating the
ability of lenders to trash a borrower’s credit score in retaliation for
the borrower’s exercise of his contractual right to default.229
Regardless of the precise policy prescription, it is time to
put to rest the assumption that a borrower who exercises the option
to default is somehow immoral or irresponsible. To the contrary,
walking away may be the most financially responsible choice if it
allows one to meet one’s unsecured credit obligations or provide
for the future economic stability of one’s family. Individuals
should not be artificially discouraged on the basis of “morality”
from making financially prudent decisions, particularly when the
party on the other side is amorally operating according to market
norms and could have acted to protect itself by following prudent
underwriting practices. The current housing bust should be viewed
for what it is: a market failure – not a moral failure on the part of
American homeowners. That being the case, it is time to take
morals out of the picture and search for an equitable solution to the
negative equity problem.
228
See Rebel A. Cole, The Housing-Asset Relief Program: A Plan for
Stabilizing the Housing and Securities Markets (April 22, 2009). Available at
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1338883 (proposing that “$300 billion in TARP
or stimulus funds” be “used to write down the principals on underwater
mortgages.”)
229
This limit on credit reporting should also, as discussed above, be
combined with a national anti-deficiency statute and an extension of the tax
waiver for forgiven mortgage debt.
No comments:
Post a Comment